Search This Blog

Showing posts with label substitution. Show all posts
Showing posts with label substitution. Show all posts

Saturday, 15 July 2023

A Level Economics 15: Demand Curve

 Why do demand curves normally slope downward from left to right.


The downward slope of demand curves, from left to right, is primarily driven by two key effects: the income effect and the substitution effect. Together, these effects help explain why consumers tend to buy more of a good as its price decreases.

  1. Income Effect: The income effect describes how changes in price impact consumers' purchasing power. When the price of a good decreases, consumers can afford to purchase the same quantity of the good with less income. As a result, their real income increases, allowing them to have more purchasing power for other goods and services. This leads to an increase in the quantity demanded of the lower-priced good. Conversely, when the price of a good increases, consumers may not be able to afford the same quantity with their existing income, resulting in a decrease in the quantity demanded.


  2. Substitution Effect: The substitution effect reflects consumers' tendency to switch to alternative goods when there is a change in relative prices. When the price of a good falls, it becomes relatively cheaper compared to other goods. Consumers perceive it as a better value and tend to substitute other goods with the lower-priced good. As a result, they increase their quantity demanded of the lower-priced good. Conversely, when the price of a good rises, consumers may switch to alternative goods that are now relatively cheaper, leading to a decrease in the quantity demanded of the higher-priced good.

Combining the income effect and the substitution effect, we observe the overall downward slope of the demand curve. As the price of a good decreases, consumers experience a higher real income and a greater incentive to substitute other goods with the lower-priced good. Both effects contribute to an increase in the quantity demanded. Conversely, as the price rises, the income effect reduces consumers' purchasing power, while the substitution effect encourages them to seek alternatives, resulting in a decrease in the quantity demanded.

It is worth noting that the downward slope of the demand curve assumes ceteris paribus, meaning other factors influencing demand, such as income and preferences, remain constant. Changes in these factors can shift the entire demand curve, altering the quantity demanded at any given price. However, the income and substitution effects provide a foundational understanding of why demand curves typically slope downward from left to right.

Saturday, 17 June 2023

A Level Economics Essay 10: Development Policies

Consider how effective the interventionist policies of import substitution and export-led industrialisation are likely to be in raising the levels of economic growth and development in LEDCs. 

Import substitution and export-led industrialization are two interventionist policies that countries can adopt to promote economic growth and development. Let's consider how effective these policies are likely to be in raising the levels of economic growth and development in LEDCs (Less Economically Developed Countries).

  1. Import Substitution: Import substitution is a policy strategy where a country aims to reduce its dependence on imported goods by promoting domestic production of those goods. The idea is to protect domestic industries from foreign competition and foster self-sufficiency. LEDCs adopting import substitution policies typically impose high tariffs and trade barriers on imported goods, making them more expensive and less competitive compared to domestically produced goods.

The infant industry argument comes into play in import substitution policies. According to this argument, emerging industries in LEDCs may initially face disadvantages compared to established industries in developed countries. They may lack economies of scale, experience higher production costs, and face technological and managerial challenges. To overcome these obstacles and enable the growth of these industries, protectionist measures are implemented.

However, import substitution policies have shown mixed results in raising economic growth and development. While they may initially protect domestic industries and promote industrialization, there are several drawbacks:

a) Lack of competitiveness: Import substitution policies often lead to the development of industries that are not internationally competitive. Due to limited exposure to global competition, these industries may struggle to innovate, achieve economies of scale, and produce high-quality goods at competitive prices.

b) Limited market size: LEDCs generally have smaller domestic markets compared to developed countries. Relying solely on domestic demand can limit the growth potential of industries. Without access to international markets, firms may face challenges in achieving economies of scale and attracting investment.

c) Dependency on inefficient industries: Import substitution policies may lead to the development of industries that are protected from competition but are inefficient and less productive. This can result in a misallocation of resources and hinder overall economic growth.

Example: During the mid-20th century, many LEDCs, including India and some Latin American countries, implemented import substitution policies. While they initially aimed to reduce dependency on imports and develop domestic industries, the results varied. Some industries thrived, but others became inefficient and uncompetitive. Over time, many countries shifted towards more market-oriented policies to promote economic growth.

  1. Export-Led Industrialization: Export-led industrialization is a policy approach where a country focuses on developing industries that can compete in international markets and promotes exports as a driver of economic growth. This strategy involves implementing policies such as export incentives, infrastructure development, investment in human capital, and market-oriented reforms to attract foreign investment and boost exports.

Export-led industrialization has been relatively more successful in promoting economic growth and development compared to import substitution policies. Some reasons include:

a) Access to larger markets: By focusing on exports, LEDCs can tap into larger international markets, allowing their industries to achieve economies of scale and expand production. Export-oriented industries are driven by international demand, which can provide sustained growth opportunities.

b) Technological spillovers: Engaging in global trade can expose LEDCs to advanced technologies and knowledge from developed countries. This transfer of technology can contribute to productivity improvements and innovation, benefiting the overall economy.

c) Foreign direct investment (FDI): Export-led industrialization policies often attract foreign investment, which brings in capital, technology, and managerial expertise. FDI can help boost industrialization, create employment opportunities, and enhance productivity in LEDCs.

Example: China and Japan are notable examples of countries that successfully implemented export-led industrialization policies. China, through its policy reforms and export-oriented approach, has become a global manufacturing powerhouse, exporting a wide range of goods to countries around the world. Japan also pursued export-led industrialization after World War II and transformed into a major exporter of automobiles, electronics, and machinery.

In conclusion, while both import substitution and export-led industrialization have been employed by LEDCs, export-led industrialization has generally proven more effective in raising economic growth and development. By focusing on exports, LEDCs can access larger markets, benefit from technological spillovers, and attract foreign investment. However, each country's specific circumstances and policy implementation play a crucial role in determining the success of these strategies. The infant industry argument provides a theoretical justification for protectionist measures under import substitution policies, acknowledging the initial disadvantages faced by emerging industries. However, striking a balance between protection and competitiveness is essential to avoid long-term inefficiencies and promote sustainable development.

Friday, 12 May 2023

One group of people can’t substitute their way out of inflation

Tim Harford in The FT

In a laboratory in College Station, Texas, in 1990, six lab rats pressed levers and lapped at tubes as root beer and tonic water were released. They were participating in the quest for an elusive quarry: the Giffen good. 

Robert Giffen was born in Lanarkshire in 1837, the year of Queen Victoria’s accession. He would become by turns assistant editor at The Economist, chief statistician at the Board of Trade, President of the Royal Statistical Society and co‑founder of the Royal Economic Society. An eminent Victorian indeed, even if one biographer sniffed, “He was one of those figures . . . whose not inconsiderable power and prestige appears to be disproportionate to their actual contribution to economic science.” Ouch. 

Yet Giffen’s name is known to every economics student. This is not because of the research he published, but because of a thought experiment which reached his contemporary Alfred Marshall, who put it in his inescapable textbook Principles of Economics. The idea is that certain goods might be consumed more when their prices rise, because the increased cost backs consumers into a corner. 

Here’s how I imagined it, as an impoverished student. My staple diet was jacket potatoes with cheese or tuna mayo, bought from a nearby kebab van. Imagine that the price of potatoes rose. Ordinarily, I’d be expected to buy fewer potatoes and more of something else. 

The problem is everything else was still more expensive than potatoes. With my budget squeezed, I couldn’t afford the luxury of the cheese and tuna topping. The missing calories would come from . . . more potatoes. 

In this example, potatoes are a “Giffen good”. Potatoes were a major part of my diet; when their price rose, I effectively became poorer and switched towards the cheapest foodstuff. The cheapest foodstuff was potatoes. 

Of course, this did not actually happen. I was never that destitute and never such a potatophage. For about a century, economists looked for real examples of Giffen goods and did not find them until 1990, when economists Raymond Battalio, John Kagel and Carl Kogut demonstrated Giffen behaviour in lab rats. (The lab rats, I am assured, were well looked after by Battalio’s neighbour, a vet.) 

The researchers offered the rats quinine-flavoured water, which the rats disliked, and root beer, which they loved. The effective prices of these drinks were changed by adjusting the volume of drink released each time the rat pressed a lever. Root beer was “expensive” because it was dispensed in smaller portions. And sure enough, it proved possible to provoke Giffen behaviour: when the cheaper quinine water became less cheap, rats still needed a drink and they cut back on the luxury of root beer, drinking more quinine water. 

So are Giffen goods little more than a theoretical curiosity? Not quite. Eventually, the economists Robert Jensen, Nolan Miller and Sangui Wang used both public health data and a field experiment to demonstrate that in the poorest parts of Hunan, China, rice was a Giffen good. As Jensen wrote in 2008, “It’s funny that people have looked in crazy places for Giffen behaviour . . . and it turns out that it could be found in the most widely consumed food in the most populous nation in the history of humanity.” 

Giffen goods also teach us something important about the impact of price rises on the poorest people. One of the most basic lessons of economics is that people respond to price hikes by finding cheaper options. If apples are expensive this week, buy oranges; when the price of oranges rises and the price of apples falls, switch back to apples again. Or just look for the bargain-basement option. If a West End show is too expensive, go to the cinema. If the cinema costs too much, watch television. You don’t have to pay higher prices; you can make do with a cheaper alternative. 

Inflation is always a little lower than it seems once you allow for such substitutions. But one group of people can’t play that game: those who are already relying on the cheapest staples have nowhere to run from price rises. 

So it wasn’t quinine water in a Texas laboratory, or rice in Hunan, that made me think recently of Giffen goods. It was the alarming rise in the price of a cheese salad sandwich. The latest data from the UK show that sliced white bread has risen in price by 29 per cent over the past 12 months, with tomatoes up 16 per cent, butter up 30 per cent, cheddar cheese up 42 per cent and cucumber 55 per cent more expensive. (Headline inflation, meanwhile, is just over 10 per cent.) 

I am not claiming that cheddar cheese is essential to life; it just seems that way. Nor is it a Giffen good. But basic foodstuffs are Giffen-adjacent. They are the last resort of people who cannot afford fancier stuff. 

Food poverty campaigners — most prominently Jack Monroe — have argued that the price of these basics has risen much faster than the general rate of inflation. As I’ve written before, it’s hard to be sure if that’s true. The Office for National Statistics tends to focus on the most popular products, not the cheapest bargains, and so the relevant data is patchy and experimental. 

Whether or not inflation really is higher for the poorest households, what is not in doubt is that inflation hits them hardest. That is both because they are more vulnerable, and because they have less room for manoeuvre as they ponder their options in the supermarket aisle. The Bank of England’s chief economist, Huw Pill, recently said that, “We’re all worse off.” Maybe so. But some of us are worse off than others.