Paul Mason in The Guardian
As housing charity Shelter turns 50, the country is still plagued by overcrowding, rogue landlords, insecure tenancies and homelessness. How do we even begin to make things better?
Boys from the City Of London school on a charity walk in aid of Shelter from Blackfriars, London, to Windsor, Berkshire, on 26 March 1969. Photograph: Len Trievnor/Getty Images
Its official name was Navigation Street, and a glance at a 19th century map suggests its origin: an isolated row of terraced houses leading down to the canal that runs through the middle of my hometown.
Canals were originally called “navigations” and the people who dug them “navvies”. This term – still in use in the 1960s – was code for poor, itinerant, Irish manual workers. So we called it “Navvy Street”: it was where the poorest people in the town lived and probably served that function from when it was built to when it was knocked down and turned into a “close”.
Navigation Street was the place I thought of when the housing charity Shelter reissued documentary photographs from the 1960s to mark its 50th anniversary. If you flick through Nick Hedges’ photos now, you could be forgiven for thinking they depict some kind of uniform, northern industrial bleakness at of the time. But you’d be wrong.
Shelter and the slums: capturing bleak Britain 50 years ago
The overcrowding, dirt and abject poverty in those images shocked people because they were exceptional. Two decades of post-war social housebuilding, plus a pro-active welfare state, had done a lot to suppress poverty. Places like Navigation Street were rare by the late sixties.
Shelter was born because people realised dwindling number of classic slum streets were not the only problem: there was widespread hidden homelessness expressed through overcrowding. The private rented sector was utterly insecure and housing costs were devouring the incomes of the poor.
Skip forward 50 years and we too have rising homelessness – 54,000 families in England last year, up 36% since the financial crisis began. Housing charities record rising overcrowding, precarious tenancies, predatory landlords and unaffordable rents. The difference is it’s not only the poor who suffer.
The shared student house has been reincarnated as the shared young professional’s house, with some even forced to share rooms. According to Crisis, there are 3.5m households containing a “concealed” adult or couple in England.
Meanwhile apartments too small to live in are being built across southern England: their occupants will have jobs once considered middle class. Precarious tenancies, outlawed during the housing reform movement of the 1960s, have created a “complain and you’re out” culture.
If you wanted to photograph the modern housing problem you’d go to the coffee shops where young people perch over laptops, late into the night, rather than endure their overcrowded flat. You would photograph the sofa-surfers; the migrants forced to live in converted garages; the families packing their bags as rent hikes and benefit cuts in the private rented sector force them to move to the periphery of towns and cities, or throw themselves at the local council for help.
The root of this problem is not one of policy – though the row over social housing and housing supply will probably shape this parliament – the deeper problem is the financialisation of home ownership.
At one point, rising home ownership solved many of the problems identified the 1960s. The predictably steady rise in house prices over time, like predictable inflation, created an escalator for the working class. If you combined that with vigorous social housebuilding, as practised by both Labour and Conservative councils in the 1970s, you created affordability at both ends of the scale.
If you then dramatically slash the supply of social housing, through right-to-buy and reduced council building, you create a permanent imbalance that turns home ownership into a form of asset investment.
‘Pay to stay’ trap will force working families out of council homes
What you get then is boom and bust. And the only way to cure the bust is for the government to greet every collapse in market prices with effective state subsidies for home ownership. This, in turn, induces a speculative frenzy of one way bets – on development, on buy to let, on off-plan investment buying from abroad.
To economists who study financial frenzy, the British housing market has followed the classic curve: the certainty of rising prices and short supply draws more and more people into the market, knowing a crash cannot wipe them out – because when confronted with falling house prices, governments have used taxpayers’ money and micromanagement of the banks to halt a spiral of repossessions and falling prices.
We don’t know what Britain would look like if the same levels of explicit subsidy and implicit preference had been pumped into the social rented sector. All we know is that the current situation is not tenable.
But we can ask ourselves the following questions:
First: how much space are people entitled to live in? The market sets no limits; even such formal rules as they still exist (they are being weakened) are flouted by the young salariat.
Second: what is the optimal balance between the private, social and state-owned rented housing and the owner-occupied sector? This cannot be hard to fathom since many cities in the 1980s and early 1990s achieved housing markets that “cleared” in economic terms: in Leicester in the 1980s I had no problem finding a secure private tenancy; no problem getting the council to hound my landlord to maintain it properly; very little problem moving from there to a housing association flat; very little problem transferring, as a key worker, from there to a council flat in London. Yes, London.
Third, what do we mean by “affordable”– when it comes to either rents or prices on state-specified newbuild homes? Under both Labour, Coalition and the Conservatives the concept of affordability has become delinked from incomes and attached to a percentage of the market rate. The same state that decided nobody should be repossessed during the 2008-11 housing slump could decide that nobody has to pay more than a fixed percentage of their incomes on housing costs.
Maybe we need to start with principles: that everyone has a right to a home; that every person has a right to a minimum amount of space in that home; and that those who claim the right to own houses nobody lives in should pay a hefty, disincentivising penalty.
Yes, that’s an infringement of the market – but housing in Britain has never been a free market: it is being created and re-created through regulation and deregulation – on benefits, on affordability, on building standards, on right to buy. The point is to shape the market towards smart outcomes.
'People will forgive you for being wrong, but they will never forgive you for being right - especially if events prove you right while proving them wrong.' Thomas Sowell
Search This Blog
Showing posts with label penalty. Show all posts
Showing posts with label penalty. Show all posts
Tuesday, 9 February 2016
Tuesday, 2 April 2013
Cricket: Umpiring Decisions should be based on Facts not Opinions
Girish Menon
Should match officials base their decisions on facts or
opinions? In football a referee is not required to declare a goal based purely
on his opinion. However in cricket an umpire could end a batsman's tenure at
the crease based on a conjecture of what would have been if the ball had not
been illegally impeded by the batsman. Yes I refer to the LBW decision, an odd
method of dismissing a batsman that relies entirely on the forecasting ability
of the umpire or the more modern DRS technology.
In football if a defender stops the ball's progress towards
the goal using his hands the referee does not have to adjudicate on what would
have happened to the ball if the defender had not stopped it illegally. The
errant footballer maybe punished with a red card and a penalty given to the
opposite side but a goal is never declared. In other words at no time is a
referee asked to base his decision on what would have been if the footballer
had not stopped the ball with his hands.
A batsman illegally impeding a cricket ball is cricket's
equivalent of a handball. However unlike football a cricket umpire can award a
'goal' to the opposing side for this 'foul' by the batsman. i.e. he can declare
a batsman out lbw for illegally impeding the ball.
It is this writer's opinion
that all umpiring decisions should be based on facts and not opinions. The LBW
decision, with or without DRS technology, can at best be only called an opinion
or a value judgement. And the problem with opinions is that they may not be
shared by everyone. Currently an LBW decision involves the human umpire or DRS
to forecast what would have happened if the ball had not been illegally
impeded. Since, 'forecasting is difficult, especially about the future' would
cricket not be better off if it based its decisions on facts instead of
opinions?
As for the 'cheat', the batsman who deliberately impedes a
ball's progress illegally, one can find other methods of punishing him and his
team. But declaring a 'goal' based on opinion should not be the way forward for
a modern game.
Related Posts
1. Cricket, Physics and the Laws of Probability
2. Abolish the LBW - it has no place in the modern world
Related Posts
1. Cricket, Physics and the Laws of Probability
2. Abolish the LBW - it has no place in the modern world
Wednesday, 27 March 2013
Cricket, Physics and the Laws of Probability
In the recently concluded test match between New Zealand and England an event occurred which in
this writer's opinion once again questions the predictability of an lbw
decision as a method of dismissing a batsman and especially the DRS system
which is being touted as a scientific fact. On the last ball of the 99th over
in the England
second innings the ball, to quote Andy Zaltzman in Cricinfo:
The ball ricocheted
from Prior's flailing bat/arms/head, and plonked downwards, in accordance the
traditions of gravity, onto the timbers. It did not brush the stumps. It did
not snick the stumps. It did not gently fondle the stumps. It hit the stumps.
The bails, perhaps patriotically mindful of their origins in early cricket in England all
those years ago, defied all the conventional principles of science by not
falling off.
If the stumps and
bails had behaved as cricketing precedent and Isaac Newton would have expected
them to behave, England
would have been seven wickets down with 43 overs left.
If the ball having hit the stumps fails to dislodge the
bails then doesn't it introduce even more uncertainty into a DRS based lbw
decision which its supporters claim to be irrefutable evidence? This incident
requires that in an lbw appeal the DRS should not only predict whether the
ball, if not impeded by the batsman illegally, would have gone on to hit the
stumps but also if it would dislodge the bails.
Supporters of the DRS rely on the infallibility of
scientific laws to promote their support for technology. Then, like true
scientists they should admit the weakness of their science whenever an anomaly
appears. Assuming for a moment that these scientific laws are infallible then
how do they explain the reprieve that Prior obtained? Also, shouldn't the DRS have been used to declare Prior out
since the ball had actually hit the stumps?
Hence I would like to make a suggestion which may unite the
supporters and opponents of the DRS. I suggest that the LBW as a method of
dismissing a batsman should be struck off from the laws of cricket. Instead, a
run penalty should be imposed on the batsman every time the ball comes in
contact with an 'illegal' part of
his/her body. The DRS could be used to adjudicate on this decision. The penalty
could be ten runs and increasing every
time the batsman uses such illegitimate methods to stay at the crease.
Thursday, 19 July 2012
Time to explode the myth that the private sector is always better
Steve Richards in The Independent
The deeply embedded assumption that a slick, efficient, agile, selfless private sector delivers high-quality services for the public is being challenged once more in darkly comic circumstances. Those inadvertent egalitarians from the security firm G4S have failed to recruit enough security officers so it seems anyone will be able to wander in to watch the 100 metres final. Or at least that would have been the case if the public sector had not come to the rescue in the form of the army.
What an emblematic story of changing times. From the late 1970s until 2008, the fashionable orthodoxy insisted that the public sector alone was the problem. Advocates of the orthodoxy took a knock or two when the banking crisis cast light on parts of the pampered, sheltered and partially corrupt financial sector. Now we get a glimpse of incompetence and greed in another part of the private sector. As light is shed wider and deeper, we keep our fingers crossed that the public sector can rescue the Olympics from chaos.
The pattern is familiar but has been obscured until the arrival of this accessibly vivid example, an Olympic Games staged in a city paranoid about security without many security officers. For decades, private companies were hired on lucrative contracts for projects that the state could never allow to fail. If the companies delivered what was required, they earned a fortune. If they failed, the taxpayer found the money to meet the losses and those responsible for the cock-up often moved on to new highly paid jobs.
The lesson should have been learnt when Labour's disastrous Public Private Partnership for the London Underground collapsed, as this was another highly accessible example of lawyers, accountants and private companies making a fortune and failing to deliver. The Underground could never close, so all involved knew that in the event of failure, the Government or the Mayor of London would be forced to intervene. Boris Johnson described the arrangement at the time as "a colossal waste of money".
He was right, but that has not stopped his colleagues in Government looking to contract out to the private sector at every available opportunity. Andrew Lansley had hoped to make the NHS a great new playground for companies seeking an easy profit. He still might do so. Expect Michael Gove's so-called free schools to become profit-making enterprises if the Conservatives win the next election, and perhaps the academies, too. Maybe there will be a G4S-sponsored school.
G4S already runs prisons and some of the police operations that are being increasingly contracted out to private companies. The welfare-to-work contract secured by another company, much hailed by gullible ministers when the deal was announced as an example of efficiency and effectiveness, is already under critical scrutiny.
A fortnight ago, I argued that we are living through a slow British revolution partly as a result of the financial crisis and the exposure of reckless, unaccountable leadership from the City. The era of light regulation that allowed some bankers without much obvious talent to make a fortune is over. Now, slowly, the assumption held from Thatcher to Blair to Cameron that the delivery of public services should lie with the private sector is being overturned, too.
As is always the case in British revolutions, the change is being driven by startling events and not by political leadership. The Coalition still burns with an ideological zeal formed in the 1980s, the Conservative wing at one with Orange Book Liberal Democrats in their indiscriminate hunger for a smaller state and their undying faith in the private sector.
At the top of both parties, there are crusading advocates of an outdated vision that places too much faith in the likes of G4S and not enough in the potential dependability of a more efficient and accountable public sector.
This is not to argue that the public sector is perfect. Parts of it are complacently inefficient and paralysed by a sense of undeserved entitlement. The Coalition deserves some credit for seeking to increase transparency and accountability in an often over-managed and wasteful sector. In the case of the Olympics debacle and other equivalent deals, part of the culpability lies with government departments that negotiate on behalf of the taxpayer.
Last week, The Independent revealed that there had been no penalty clause in the G4S contract. On Tuesday, its unimpressive chief executive told the Home Affairs Committee that the company still expected to collect £57m for its contribution to the Olympic Games, an expectation that brings to mind once more that damning, ubiquitous phrase from the old Britain: "rewards for failure".
Who draws up these contracts? Which ministers sign them off? Why is their instinct always to outsource when there is now a mountain of evidence that failure follows?
Instead of focusing on the arduously unglamorous task of making the public sector more efficient and adaptable, ministers, like their New Labour predecessors, prefer still the deceptive swagger of the incompetent entrepreneur. The gullibility is more extraordinary now we finally get to know more about these supposed geniuses. Senior bankers earning millions stutter hesitantly when questioned by unthreatening MPs on select committees, incapable of articulating a case. Nick Buckles from G4S was so thrown by the Home Affairs Committee that he lapsed into a debate about whether the few security guards he had managed to hire spoke "fluent English", claiming not to know what such a term might mean. One of the great revelations since Britain's slow revolution began in 2008 is how many unimpressive mediocrities had risen in the unquestioning, unaccountable darkness that, until recently, acted as a protective layer for parts of the private sector.
But in the end look who is ultimately held to account. The Home Secretary, Theresa May, was called to the Commons twice this week to answer questions about what went wrong. She will be back in September. A government can outsource but it will still be held responsible, quite rightly, for the delivery of public services.
So political survival should motivate ministers in future to draw up much tighter deals with companies and to focus more on improving the public sector rather than expensively by-passing it. The voters have had enough of these abuses and yet, trapped by the past, some ministers show an ideological inclination to be abused for a little longer.
Wednesday, 4 July 2012
Abolish the LBW - it has no place in the modern world
by Girish Menon
The cricket world appears to be at war between technophiles
who argue that technology (DRS) can be used to solve some of its most vexatious
decisions while others claim that technology may solve questions about fact but is inadequate to solve questions based on
conjecture and opinion. In continuance with my earlier piece, 'Would the BCCI act like Mandela' (original draft), this article will argue that LBW is an archaic form of
dismissing a batsman, it calls for repealing the LBW laws and will suggest alternative
measures to prevent a batsman illegitimately impeding the progress of the
cricket ball.
Imagine the following two scenarios:
1. Person X is caught on camera unsheathing his knife and
plunging it into the body of person Z who is asleep in his bed. As a result Z
is dead.
2. Person Y is caught on camera unsheathing his knife,
however, unlike X, Y was unable to plunge his knife into the body of person Z.
As a result Z is still alive today.
What do you think will be the punishment meted out to
persons X and Y in a court of law? If this is a country still practising the death
penalty, will person Y be awarded the highest form of punishment like person X?
This writer believes that person Y will not be given the same punishment as
person X since person Y has not committed the crime of murder.
This analogy to a murder trial resembles the judgement
involved in an LBW decision. In an LBW appeal the bowler claims that if the
ball had not been illegitimately impeded then it would have definitely hit the
stumps. Hence the batsman who impeded the ball must be given the batsman's
equivalent of the death penalty. The technophiles, who are in favour of using
DRS to adjudicate on LBW decisions, argue that technology can definitely be
used to prove that the ball would have hit the stumps if it had not been
impeded. To technophiles I would ask a question that is the favourite of
detectives, 'Where is the body?' Since the body, i.e. the stumps are
undisturbed, is alive no murder has yet been committed and therefore there is
no case for the prosecution.
Hence I would like to make a suggestion which may unite the
technophiles and those opposed to using the DRS for an LBW decision. I suggest
that the LBW as a method of dismissing a batsman should be struck off from the
laws of cricket. Instead, a run penalty should be imposed on the batsman every
time the ball comes in contact with his 'illegitimate' body parts. The DRS
could be used to ascertain such decisions as well. The penalty could be similar
to the one imposed on a fielding team when the ball hits its helmet parked on
the field.
The LBW decision is an opinion and the law courts have
increasingly realised the inadequacies of expert opinions to convicting
defendants. Similarly, cricket should evolve into modernity by getting rid of
decisions based on opinions and try to be governed only by facts. I look forward to this debate.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)