Search This Blog

Wednesday 22 October 2008

It's all poor people's fault, isn't it?

 

Mark Steel  

All economists know that banking crashes are caused by Somalian fishermen

I'm not sure what makes it official that the recession's started, but one way of measuring the start is when the government first insists there ARE lots of vacancies, but the unemployed need to be more flexible, and better at applying for jobs, as Gordon Brown stated this week.
 
This must have been the problem in the 1930s. Millions of people became too fussy, until they perked up around 1940 when some cushy jobs came up, such as marching through the North African desert with a machine gun.
 
Brown assured us there are 600,000 vacancies, just as Major in 1991 and Tebbit in 1982 told us there were plenty of jobs, if only people would look for them. But even if these vacancies were magically all filled, a minister would tell us, "The unemployed must be prepared to develop new skills, such as murdering people who have a job, then applying to take their place. My granddad taught me those values, often recalling how, rather than sit around whining, he poisoned his way into the Post Office for nine and six a week. It's time we revived the old saying, 'Assassinate, don't beg off the state'."
 
Another sign that we're in recession is the government blames immigrants. So Phil Woolas, the immigration minister, has said the numbers allowed to come here must be cut, given the economic problems. This is even cleverer than blaming the unemployed, as in effect it's saying, "I'll tell you who's brought this on – people who've never been here." As any economist knows, banking crashes are caused by Somalian fishermen.
 
This is all in the recession handbook – to ensure governments and banks don't get the blame by blaming the victims. If the criminal system worked the same way, judges would spend all day telling people who'd been burgled, "You have been found guilty of being burgled. You appear to have no sense of how much a burden to the rest of us you've become. Maybe you need lessons in how to make an effort in life, such as the fine example shown by the man who burgled you. You don't catch him sitting around grumbling about his missing CDs, do you?"
 
Or the government could set up its own counselling service, at which a counsellor leans gently forward and says reassuringly, "You've told me how you were beaten up by your stepfather, and locked in a cupboard, and made to eat mouthfuls of insects, so the important point for you is to tell yourself at all times, especially in your most fragile moments, that this was your fault. There might be occasions when you feel someone else was to blame, but no, it was all down to you. Next."
With similar sensitivity Peter Mandelson has announced that, to help business survive the recession, there will be a postponement of new regulations allowing flexible working for parents. And Mandelson's only been back a week. Give him another fortnight and he'll announce, "Working parents have a variety of options available to them, such as selling their children to China to work in a clothing factory or train as a gymnast. I, for example, had to make myself available at all hours to lounge on a Russian billionaire's yacht. I don't go around saying, 'I'm sorry Mr Oligarch, I can only lounge until four in the afternoon'. I'm prepared to make sacrifices."
 
So perhaps anyone who finds themselves unemployed, or homeless or otherwise broke as a result of this recession, should march to the House of Commons and announce "I demand to be nationalised. Bail me out for a million and I can carry on, because if I go under, who knows WHAT I might bring down with me."


Get the best wallpapers on the Web – FREE. Click here!

India's Puzzled Vendors of Washington Consensus

 

Ever since the crisis originating on Wall Street has spread far and wide like a contagion, the clamour for state intervention to save the global economy in general and financial institutions in particular has become vociferous. Those who, till the other day, were decrying the role of state in the running of economy and were singing the virtues of the Washington Consensus-based globalization have gone into hibernation. Nobody now talks of 'the magic of the marketplace' and of great sermons by Hayek and Milton Friedman. In India, Gurcharan Das, Surajit Bhalla, Raghuram Rajan, Kaushik Basu and company seem so demoralized that they are no longer thundering against rural loan waiver, NREGS (National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme), the so-called Hindu rate of growth, 'disastrous acts' like nationalization of commercial banks by Mrs. Indira Gandhi and the initiation of economic planning by Nehru. Strangely enough, the recommendations by the Raghuram Rajan Committee like privatization of nationalized banks and bringing in convertibility of the rupee on capital account and making pension funds available to the players on the bourse are no longer talked about. Nobody is cautioning against moral hazard when the government is announcing one measure after another for rescuing financial institutions while, till the other day, it was frequently being mentioned for mobilizing opposition to rural loan waiver. Please recall how Kaushik Basu was pontificating in the columns of The Hindustan Times that NREGS would encourage laziness.

 

It seems strange that most of these gentlemen who have been lambasting economic strategy of the Nehru-Indira Gandhi regimes have become suddenly speechless. Had banks and other financial institutions not been nationalized and state-regulated, India would have been in a miserable plight. India escaped in the 1990s and has largely escaped now from the contagion, thanks to Nehru-Indira Gandhi strategy of economic development, loudly decried by Gurcharan Das in his book which has been lauded by the corporate-controlled press. Thanks to the much abused Left, reforms like capital account convertibility of the rupee, privatization of public sector financial institutions, smashing the organized labour movement and making pension funds available to casino players could not go ahead. Thus it was not without reason that a great relief was felt by the corporate world and the media controlled by it when the Left parted company with the UPA government and it was hoped that the chariot of reforms would go ahead at a break-neck speed without any hindrance. Alas! this has not happened nor is any possibility of its happening in the near future.

 

Most of these vendors have their hawking confined only to the English-knowing middle class. The only person that has been effectively peddling the Washington Consensus-based globalization among the poor and the downtrodden in India has been Chandrabhan Prasad, a smart journalist from the most populous state of India, Uttar Pradesh. He writes in both English and Hindi with seemingly logical arguments. He takes part in discussions on both electronic media and other public forums. It goes to his credit that leaders and people, cutting across the ideological divide, are enchanted with him. He writes regularly for the pro-BJP daily The Pioneer and was recently taken to America by, Ram Vilas Paswan, a minister in the central government, who claims to be secular.

 

Chandrabhan Prasad's importance as a vendor of the Washington Consensus-based globalization has been underlined by The New York Times (August 30) correspondent Ms Somini Sengupta in her article entitled "Crusader Sees Wealth as Cure for India Caste Bias". The same piece has been carried by its global edition, The International Herald Tribune (IHT), in its September 1 issue, under a new heading, "Even untouchables get a taste of the New India: Economic growth shatters caste order". The IHT is printed in Hyderabad and reaches the doorsteps of its Indian readers every morning.

 

The dispatch filed by Ms Sengupta is from his native village, Gaddopur, of Azamgarh district in U.P. with two large photographs, one of them prominently displaying his picture. Chandrabhan Prasad holds that, Dalits (formerly untouchables, comprising the lowest rung of the Hindu society) can better their lot and get rid of their age-old social and economic sufferings, exploitation and neglect by embracing the Washington Consensus-based globalization as this will lead to a decisive improvement in their educational, cultural and economic position. Very soon they will be able to come on par with non-Dalits.

 

Whenever he "visits his ancestral village in ... feudal badlands of northern India," he tells "his fellow untouchables: Get rid of your cattle, because the care of animals demands children's labor. Invest in your children's education instead of jewelry or land. Cities are good for Dalit outcastes like us, and so is India's new capitalism." A chain-smoking Chandrabhan Prasad, now in his forties, was once a Maoist, always carrying a pistol and recruiting followers always ready to kill upper caste landlords, but now he is a completely changed man. He has now come to the conclusion that the salvation of the Dalits does not lie in Maoism but in "new capitalism" that has been growing in India since 1991 and he firmly believes that "economic liberalization in India is about to do the unthinkable: Destroy the caste system." It has already enabled a large number of Dalits who have migrated to urban areas since 1991 to "escape hunger and humiliation." Thus Ms Sengupta of The New York Times comments: "At a time of tremendous upheaval in India, Prasad is a lightning rod for one of the country's most wrenching debates: Has India's embrace of economic reforms really uplifted those who were consigned for centuries to the bottom of the social ladder?"

 

He does not attach much value to the government-run welfare programmes aimed at ameliorating the conditions of the Dalits nor is the affirmative action going to be effective in getting many jobs to them. He wants them to have devotion to "the Dalit goddess," i.e., English language which can go a long way to help their liberation. He looks down upon socialism and "has moved to the right" and is vociferously "contemptuous of leftists, and delights in taunting them."

 

As a sign of progress by the Dalits under the new dispensation, he points out that in his own district now almost all Dalit bridegrooms ride cars rather than horses to their weddings as compared to just 27 per cent in 1990, a year before the era of Washington Consensus-based globalization was heralded by Narasimha Rao-Manmohan Singh duo. Only a few decades ago, the upper caste-dominated Hindu society would not have allowed Dalit bridegrooms to ride even horses to their weddings. The credit for this change goes largely to a booming economy. In his own words, "It has pulled them out of the acute poverty they were in and the day-to-day humiliation of working for a landlord."

 

There are around 200 million Dalits in India. Chandrabhan Prasad, with a generous financial grant from the University of Pennsylvania, is conducting a sample survey of 20,000 Dalit households in order to know how their daily life has been impacted by economic liberalization since 1991. The preliminary results, he says, indicate that the change is for the better and Dalits are giving up their traditional caste occupations.

 

The horde of both Indian and foreign journalists taken by Chandrabhan Prasad, just a few weeks before the global financial melt down set in, to show the changing face of the Dalit society under Washington Consensus-based globalization was not convinced. To quote Ms Somini Sengupta, "On a journey across these villages with Prasad, it is difficult to square the utter destitution of his people with Dalit empowerment. The government health center has collapsed into a pile of bricks. Few homes have toilets. Children run barefoot."

 

In his own village itself, "the Dalit neighborhood still sits on the edge of the village—so as not to pollute the others, the thinking goes—and in the monsoon, when the fields are flooded, the only way to reach the Dalits' homes is to tramp ankle deep in mud. The land that leads to the Dalit enclave is owned by intermediate castes, and they have not allowed for it to be used to build a proper brick lane."

 

Thus, obviously, there is a divergence between the reality and the myth propagated by him. There is no doubt that substantial benefits of economic development since the 1950s have trickled down to Dalits but they have been cornered largely by the upper segments of the Dalits that include newly-emerged politicians, bureaucrats and businessmen.

 

If Dalits follow the advice of Chandrabhan Prasad and sell off whatever meager property they have and migrate to urban areas, most of them will be compelled to live in slums and work as casual labourers. In the absence of any movable or immovable property they will not be able to raise funds to set up and carry on their own enterprises. In the present state of the slums, it will not be easy for most of their children to get proper education and training to secure good jobs nor will they live a healthy life. As the Australian journalist, Gregory David Roberts has in his widely read novel Shantaram has depicted, the slums are dens of crimes and once a person lands in them, it is difficult for him to get out. In fact, Chandrabhan Prasad is trying to encourage a new enclosure movement whereby Dalits and other lower class people leave their villages to migrate to urban areas to provide a pool of cheap unorganized labour without any protection as regards terms and conditions of work. In the villages deserted by them contract farming and SEZs (Special Economic Zones) by the corporate sector can prosper without any local resistance. It is needless to say whose interests he intends to serve.

 

Ever since neo-liberal globalization has started taking roots in India, people like him have been singing its praise. He, as compared with others, has seemingly greater credibility because he comes from Dalit community and this is the reason that he has become an icon for the corporate-controlled media and gullible intellectuals. Theodore Dreiser in his novel An American Tragedy and Arthur Miller in his play Death of A Salesman, long ago, demonstrated that the much touted American dream was more of a myth than reality. In recent times, Joseph Stiglitz, Nobel prize winning economist, has underlined that American dream is nothing but a mirage. Rarely a person goes up in socio-economic hierarchy mainly by dint of his intelligence, hard work and efficiency.

 

In Indian cities only a tiny proportion of Dalit children are able to go beyond primary schools. Every morning one finds a large number of children from slums collecting garbage or begging in the name of some god or goddess. For them Chandrabhan Prasad's prescription is meaningless. Even in America, as Nobel laureate Saul Bellow's son Adam Bellow in his book In Defense of Nepotism has demonstrated, family background and connections are big factors in the rise of a person in socio-economic hierarchy. Washington Consensus-based globalization is not for equitable distribution of the gains but advocates only the "trickle-down strategy". Obviously, Chandrabhan Prasad's expectations are misplaced. The recent turn of events has put a big question mark before Washington Consensus-based globalization, thus rubbishing all the assertions of Chandrabhan Prasad.

gmishra@girishmishra.com




For the best free wallpapers from MSN Click here!

Monday 20 October 2008

TOWARDS A NEW ECONOMICS: Questioning Growth

by Herman E. Daly

Any discussion of the relative merits of a stationary, no-growth economy, and its opposite, the economy in which wealth and population are growing, must recognize some important quantitative and qualitative differences between rich and poor countries and social classes. Consider the familiar ratio of gross national product (GNP) to total population (P). This ratio per capita annual product (GNP/P), is the measure usually employed to distinguish rich from poor countries. In spite of its many shortcomings, it does have the virtue of reflecting in one ratio the two fundamental life processes of production and reproduction. Two questions must be asked of both numerator and denominator for both rich and poor nations: namely, what is the quantitative rate of growth, and qualitatively, exactly what is it that is growing?

The rate of growth in the denominator P is much higher in poor countries. While mortality is tending to equality at low levels throughout the world, fertility in poor nation is roughly twice that of rich nations. No other social or economic index divides the world so clearly and consistently into "developed" and "undeveloped" as does fertility.

Qualitatively, the incremental population in poor countries consists largely of hungry illiterates, while in rich countries it consists largely of well-fed members of the middle class. The incremental person in poor countries contributes negligibly to production, but makes few demands on world resources. The incremental person in a rich country adds to his country's GNP, but his high standard of living contributes greatly to depletion of the world's resources and pollution of its spaces.

The numerator, GNP, is growing at roughly the same rate in rich and poor countries—around 4 or 5 percent annually, with the poor countries probably growing slightly faster. Nevertheless, because of their more rapid population growth, the per capita income of poor countries is growing more slowly than that of rich countries. Consequently the gap between rich and poor widens over time.

Incremental GNP in rich and poor nations has very different qualitative significance. At some point, probably already passed in the United States, an extra unit of GNP costs more than it is worth. Extra GNP in a poor country, assuming it does not go mainly to the richest class of that country, represents satisfaction of relatively basic wants (food, clothing, shelter, basic education, etc,) while extra GNP in a rich county, assuming it does not go mainly to the poorest class, represents satisfaction of relatively trivial wants (more electric toothbrushes, yet another brand of cigarettes, more force-feeding through advertising, etc.).

The upshot of these differences is that for the poor, growth in GNP is probably still a good thing, while for the rich it is probably a bad thing. Growth in population, however, is a bad thing for both; for the rich because it makes growth in GNP less avoidable, and for the poor because it makes growth in GNP, and especially per capita GNP, more difficult. The following discussion is concerned exclusively with a rich, affluent-effluent economy such as that of the United States, and will seek to define more clearly the concept of a stationary-state economy, see why it is necessary, consider its economic and social implications, and finally, comment on an emerging political economy of finite wants and non-growth.

THE ART OF GETTING ON

Over a century ago John Stuart Mill, the great synthesizer of classical economics, spoke of the stationary state in words that could hardly be more pertinent today: It must always have been seen, more or less distinctly, by political economists, that the increase in wealth is not boundless; that at the end of what they term the progressive state lies the stationary state, that all progress in wealth is but a postponement of this, and that each step in advance is an approach to it.

I cannot...regard the stationary state of capital and wealth with the unaffected aversion so generally manifested towards it by political economist of the old school. I am inclined to believe that it would be, on the whole, a very considerable improvement on our present condition. I confess I am not charmed with the ideal of life held out by those who think that the normal state of human beings is that of struggling to get on; that the trampling, crushing, elbowing, and treading on each other's heels which forms the existing type of social life, are the most desirable lot of human kind.

....The northern and middle states of America are a specimen of this stage of civilization in very favorable circumstances...and all that these advantages seem to have yet done for them...is that the life of the whole of one sex is devoted to dollar-hunting, and the other to breeding dollars-hunters...

I know not why it should be a matter of congratulations that persons who are already richer than anyone needs to be, should have doubled their means of consuming things which give little or no pleasure except as representative of wealth...It is only in the backward countries of the world that increased production is still an important object; in those most advanced, what is economically needed is a better distribution, of which one indispensable means is a stricter restraint on population...the density of population necessary to enable mankind to obtain, in the greatest degree, all the advantages both of cooperation and of social intercourse, has in all the most populous countries, been attained...It is not good for a man to be kept perforce at all times in the presence of his species...Nor is there much satisfaction in contemplating the world with nothing left to the spontaneous activity of nature...If the earth must lose that great portion of its pleasantness which it owes to things that the unlimited increase of wealth and population would extirpate from it, for the mere purpose of enabling it to support a larger, but not a happier or better population, I sincerely hope, for the sake of posterity, that they will be content to be stationary, long before a necessity compels therm to it.

It is scarcely necessary to remark that a stationary condition of capital and population implies no stationary state of human improvement. There would be as much scope as ever for all kinds of mental culture, and moral and social progress; as much and much more likelihood of it being improved, when minds cease to be engrossed by the art of getting on. Even the industrial arts might be as earnestly and as successfully cultivated, with this sole difference, that instead of serving no purpose but the increase of wealth, industrial improvements would produce their legitimate effect, that of abridging labor.

The direction in which political economy has evolved in the last hundred years is not along the path suggested in the quotation. In fact, most economists are hostile to the notion of stationary state and dismiss Mill's discussion as "strongly colored by his 'social views "'(as if the neo-classical theories were not so colored! ); "nothing so much as a prolegomenon to Galbraith's Affluent Society"; or "hopelessly dated." The truth of the matter, however, is that Mill is even more relevant today than in his own time.

DISCOVERING AN INVISIBLE FOOT

Stationary state signifies a constant stock of physical wealth (capital), and a constant stock of people (population). Naturally these stocks do not remain constant by themselves. People die and wealth is physically consumed (worn out, depreciated). Therefore the stocks must be maintained by a rate of inflow (birth, production) equal to the rate of outflow (death, consumption). But this equality may obtain, and stocks remain constant, with high rate of throughput (inflow equal to outflow) or with a low rate.

This definition of stationary state is not complete until the rates of throughput by which the constant stocks are maintained are specified. For a number of reasons the rate of throughput should be as low as possible. For an equilibrium stock the average age at "death" of its members is the reciprocal of the throughput. The faster the water flows through the tank, the less time an average drop spends in the tank. For the population, a low rate of throughput (low birth and death rates) means a high life expectancy and is desirable for that reason alone—at least within limits. For the stock of wealth, a low rate of throughput (low production and low consumption) means greater life expectancy or durability of goods and less time sacrificed to production. This means more "leisure" or non job time to be divided into consumption time, personal and household maintenance time, culture time, and idleness. This too seems socially desirable.

But to these reasons for the desirability of a low rate of maintenance throughput, must be added some reasons for the impracticability of high rate. Since matter and energy cannot be created, production inputs must be taken from the environment, leading to depletion. Since matter and energy cannot be destroyed, an equal amount of matter and energy in the form of waste must be returned to environment, leading to pollution. Hence lower rates of throughput lead to less depletion and pollution, higher rates to more. The limits regarding what rates of depletion and pollution are tolerable must be supplied by ecology. A definite limit to the size of maintenance flows of specific materials is set by ecological thresholds that, if exceeded, cause system breaks. To keep flows below these limits we can operate on two variables; the size of the stocks and the durability of the stocks. As long as we are well below these thresholds, economic cost-benefit calculations regarding depletion and pollution can be relied upon as a guide. But as these thresholds are approached, "marginal cost" and "marginal benefits" become meaningless, and Alfred Marshall's motto, "nature does not make jumps," and most of neoclassical marginalist economics becomes inapplicable. The "marginal" cost of one more step may be to fall into the precipice.

Of the two variables, size of stocks and durability of stocks, only the second requires further clarification. Durability here means more than just how long a commodity lasts. It also includes the number of times that the waste output can be reused as input in the production of something else. Nature has furnished the ideal model of a closed-loop system of material cycles powered by the sun. To the extent that our technology can imitate nature's solar-powered closed-loop, then our stock of wealth will tend to become as durable as our water, soil, and air which are the real sources of wealth since it is only through their agency that plants are able to capture vital solar energy. The ideal is that all physical outputs should be usable either as inputs in some other man-made process, or as non-disruptive inputs into natural material cycles.

The stationary state of wealth and population is maintained by an inflow of low entropy matter energy and outflow of an equal quantity of high entropy matter-energy. (Low entropy matter-energy is highly structured, organized matter and easily usable free energy. High entropy matter-energy is randomized, useless bits of matter, and latent, unusable energy.) Stocks of wealth and people feed on low entropy. Low entropy inputs are received from the environment in exchange for high entropy outputs to the environment. In this overall sense there can be no closed loop or recycling of both matter and energy because of the second law of thermodynamics. However, within the overall system there can be subsystems of individual processes arranged so that their material input-output links form a closed loop. Conceivably all processes in the stationary state could be arranged to form a material closed loop. But the recycling of matter through this closed-loop "world engine" requires energy, part of which becomes irrevocably useless as it is dissipated into heat. Actually, industrial material cycles cannot be 100 per cent closed as this would require an uneconomical, if not impossible expenditure of energy. Thus some of the high entropy output takes the form of randomized bits of matter, and some takes the form of heat.

The limit to using energy to reduce material pollution is the resulting localized thermal pollution, not the very long run, universal thermodynamic heat death. Thus it is important to bear in mind that the expenditure of energy needed for recycling necessarily pollutes.

The mere expenditure of energy is not sufficient to close the material cycle, since energy must work through the agency of material implements. To recycle aluminum beer cans requires more trucks to collect the cans as well as more energy to run the trucks. More trucks require more steel, glass, etc., which require more iron ore and coal, which require still more trucks. This is the familiar web of inter-industry interdependence reflected in an input-output table.

All of these extra intermediate activities required to recycle beer cans involve some inevitable pollution as well. If we think of each industry as adding recycling to its production process, then this will generate a whole chain of direct and indirect demands on matter and energy resources that must be taken away from final demand uses and devoted to the intermediate activity of recycling. It will take more intermediate products and activities to support the same level of final output. The advantage of recycling is that it allows nations to choose the least harmful combination of material and thermal pollution.

The classical economists thought that the stationary state would be made necessary by limits on the depletion side, but the main limits now seem to be in fact occurring on the pollution side. In effect, pollution provides another foundation for the economic law of increasing costs, but has received little attention in this regard since pollution costs are social while depletion costs are usually private. On the input side the environment is partitioned into spheres of private ownership. Depletion of the environment coincides, to some degree, with depletion of the owner's wealth, and inspires at least a minimum of stewardship. On the output side, however, the waste absorption capacity of the environment is not subject to partitioning and private ownership. Air and water are used freely by all and result is a competitive, profligate exploitation—what biologist Garrett Hardin calls the "commons effect," what welfare economists call "external diseconomies," and what I like to call the "invisible foot."

Adam Smith's "invisible hand" leads private self-interest unwittingly to serve the common good. The "invisible foot" leads private self-interest to kick the common good to pieces. Private ownership and private use under a competitive market give rise to the invisible hand. Public ownership with public restraint on use gives rise to the invisible hand (and foot) of the planner. Depletion has been partially restrained by the invisible foot. It is therefore not surprising to find limits occurring mainly on the pollution side.

MINI VS. MAXI

The economic and social implications of the stationary state are enormous and revolutionary. The physical flows of production and consumption must be minimized, not maximized, subject to some agreed upon minimum standard of living and population size. The central concept must be the stock of wealth, not as presently, the flow of income and consumption. (Kenneth Boulding has been making this point since 1949, but with no effect on his fellow economists.) Furthermore, the stock must not grow. The important issue of the stationary state will be distribution, not production. The argument that everyone should be happy as long as his absolute share of the wealth increase, regardless of his relative share, will no longer be available. The arguments justifying inequality in wealth as necessary for saving, investment, and growth will lose their force. With income flows kept low, the focus will be on the distribution of income. Marginal productivity theories and "justifications" pertain only to flows and therefore are not available to explain or justify the distribution of stock ownership.

It so hard to see how ethical appeals to equal shares can be countered. Also, even though physical stocks remain constant, increased income in the form of leisure will result from continued technological improvements. How will it be distributed if not according to some ethical norm of equality? The stationary state would make fewer demands on our environmental resources, but much greater demands on our moral resources. In the past a good case could be made that leaning too heavily on scarce moral resources, rather than relying on abundant self-interest, was the road to serfdom. But in an age of rockets, hydrogen bombs, cybernetics, and genetic control, there is simply no substitute for moral resources and no alternative to relying on them, whether they prove sufficient or not.

With constant physical stocks, economic growth must be in non-physical goods, particularly leisure. Taking the benefits of technological progress in the form of increased leisure is a reversal of the historical practice of taking the benefits mainly in the form of goods and has extensive social implications. In the past, economic development has increased the physical output of a day's work while the number of hours in a day has, of course remained constant, with the result that the opportunity cost of a unit of time in terms of goods has risen. Time is worth more goods, and a good is worth less time. As time becomes more expensive in terms of goods, fewer activities are "worth the time." We become goods-rich and timepoor. Consequently we crowd more activities and more consumption into the same period of time in order to raise the return of non-work time, thereby maximizing the total time. This gives rise to what Staffan Linder has called the "harried leisure class."

Not only do we use work time more efficiently, but also personal consumption time, and we even try to be efficient in our sleep by attempting subconscious learning. Time-intensive activities (friendships, care of the aged and children, meditation and reflection) are sacrificed in favor of commodity-intensive activities (consumption). At some point people will feel rich enough to afford more time-intensive activities even at the higher price. But advertising, by constantly extolling the value of commodities, postpones this point.

From an ecological view, of course, this is exactly the reverse of what is called for. What is needed is a low relative price of time in terms of commodities. Then time-intensive activities will be substituted for material-intensive activities. To become less materialistic in our habits, we must raise the relative price of matter. Keeping physical stocks constant and using technology to increase leisure time will do just that. Thus a policy of non-material growth or leisure-only growth, in addition to being necessary for keeping physical stocks constant, has the further beneficial effect of encouraging a more generous expenditure of time and a more careful use of physical goods. A higher relative price of material intensive goods may, at first glance, be thought to encourage their production. But material goods require material inputs, so costs as well as revenues would increase, eliminating profit incentives to expand.

In the 1930's the late Bertrand Russell proposed a policy of leisure growth rather than commodity growth and viewed the unemployment question in terms of the distribution of leisure. The following words are from his essay, "In Praise of Idleness:"

Suppose that, at a given moment, a certain number of people are engaged in the manufacture of pins. They make as many pins as the world needs, working (say) eight hours a day. Someone makes an invention by which the same number of men can make twice as many pins as before. But the world does not need twice as many pins. Pins are already so cheap that hardly any more will be bought at a lower price. In a sensible world, everybody concerned in the manufacture of pins would take to working four hours instead of eight and everything else would go on as before. But in the actual world this would be thought demoralizing. The men still work eight hours, there are too many pins, some employers go bankrupt, and half the men previously concerned in making pins are thrown out of work. There is in the end just as much leisure as on the other plan, but half the men are totally idle while half are still overworked. In this way it is insured that the unavoidable leisure shall cause misery all round instead of being a universal source of happiness. Can anything more insane be imagined.

In addition to this strategy of leisure-only growth, we can internalize some pollution costs by charging effluent taxes. Economic efficiency requires only that a price be placed on environmental amenities, it does not tell us who should pay the price. The producer may claim that the use of the environment to absorb waste products is a right that all organisms and firms must of necessity enjoy, and whoever wants air and water to be cleaner than it is at any given time should pay for it. Consumers may argue that whoever makes the environment dirtier than it otherwise would be should be the one to pay. Again the issue becomes basically one of distribution—not what the price should be, but who should pay it. The fact that the price takes the form of a tax automatically decides who should receive the price—the government. But this raises more distribution issues, and the solutions to these problems are ethical, not technical.

Another possibility of non-material growth is to redistribute wealth from the low marginal utility uses of the rich to the high marginal uses of the poor, thereby increasing total social utility. Joan Robinson has noted that this egalitarian implication of the law of diminishing marginal utility was "sterilized mainly by slipping from utility to physical output as the object to be maximized." As we move back from physical output to non-physical utility, the egalitarian implications become unsterilized.

Traditional Keynesian full employment policies will no longer be available to palliate the distribution question since they require growth. By allowing full employment, growth permits the old principles of distribution (income-through jobs) to continue in effect. But with no growth in physical stocks and policy of using technological progress to increase leisure, full employment is no longer a workable principle of distribution. Furthermore, we add a new dimension to the distribution problem—how to distribute leisure.

A stationary population, with low birth and death rates, would imply a greater percentage of old people than in the present growing population, although hardly a geriatric society as some youth worshippers claim. Since old people do not work, the distribution problem is further accentuated. However, the percentage of children will diminish, so in effect there will be mainly a change in direction of transfer payments. More of the earnings of working adults will be transferred to the old and less to children.

What institutions will provide the control necessary to keep the stocks of wealth and people constant, with the minimum sacrifice of individual freedom? It would be far too simpleminded to blurt out "socialism" as the answer, since socialist states are as badly afflicted with growth mania as capitalist states. The Marxist eschatology of the classless society is based on the premise of complete abundance; consequently economic growth is exceedingly important in socialist theory and practice. And population growth, for the orthodox Marxist, cannot present problems under socialist institutions. This latter tenet has weakened a bit in recent years, but the first continues in full force. However, it is equally simpleminded to believe that our present big capital, big labor, big government, big military type of private profit capitalism is capable of the required foresight and restraint, and that the addition of a few effluent and severance taxes here and there will solve the problem. The issues are much deeper and inevitably impinge in the distribution of income and wealth.

Why do people produce junk and cajole other people into buying it? Not out of any innate love for junk or hatred of the environment, but simply in order to earn an income. If—with the prevailing distribution of wealth, income, and power-production governed by the profit motive results in the output of great amounts of noxious junk, then something is wrong with the distribution of wealth and power, the profit motive, or both. We need some principle of income distribution independent of and supplementary to their income-through jobs link. A start in this direction was made by Oskar Lange, who attempted to combine some socialist principles of distribution with the allocative efficiency advantages of the market system. However, at least as much remains to be done here as remains to be done in designing institutions for stabilizing population. But before progress can be made on their issues we must recognize their necessity and blow the whistle on growth mania.

STUNTING growth mania

Although the ideas expressed by Mill have been totally dominated by growth mania, there are an increasing number of economists who have frankly expressed their disenchantment with the growth ideology. Arguments stressing ecological limits to wealth and population have been made by Kenneth Boulding and Joseph Spengler, both past presidents of the American Economic Association. Recently E.J. Mishan, Tibor Scitovsky, and Staffan Linder have made penetrating antigrowth arguments. There is also much in Galbraith that is anti-growth—at least against growth of commodities whose desirability must be manufactured along with the product.

In spite of these beginnings, most economists are still governed by the assumption of infinite wants, or the postulate of non satiety as the mathematical economists call it. Any single want can be satisfied, but all wants in the aggregate cannot be. Wants are infinite in number if not in intensity, and the satisfaction of some wants stimulates others. If wants are infinite, growth is always justified—or so it would seem.

Even while accepting the above hypothesis, one could still object to growth mania on the grounds that given the completely inadequate definition of GNP, "growth" simply means the satisfaction of ever more trivial wants, while simultaneously creating even more powerful externalities that destroy ever more basic environmental amenities. To defend ourselves against these externalities, we produce even more, and instead of subtracting the purely defensive expenditures, we add them. For example, the medical bills paid for treatment of cigarette-induced cancer and pollution-induced emphysema are added to GNP, when in a welfare sense they clearly should be subtracted. This should be labeled swelling, not growth. The satisfaction of wants crated by brainwashing and "hog washing" the public over the mass media also represents mostly swelling.

A policy of maximizing GNP is practically equivalent to a policy of maximizing depletion and pollution. This results from the fact that GNP measures the flow of a physical aggregate. Since matter and energy cannot be created, production is simply the transformation of raw material inputs extracted from the environment; consequently, maximizing the physical flow of production implies maximizing depletion. Since matter and energy cannot be destroyed, consumption is merely the transformation into waste of GNP, resulting in environmental pollution. One may hesitate to say "maximal" pollution on the grounds that the production inflow into the stock can be greater than the consumption outflow as long as the stock increases as it does in a growing economy.

To the extent that wealth becomes more durable, the production of waste can be kept low by expanding the stock. But is this in fact what happens? If one wants to maximize production, one must have a market. Increasing the durability of goods reduces the replacement demand. The faster things wear out, the greater can be the flow of production, one must have a market. Increasing the durability of goods reduces the replacement demand. The faster things wear out, the greater can be the flow of production. To the extent that consumer reaction and weakening competition permit, there is every incentive to minimize durability. Planned obsolescence, programmed self-destruction, and other waste making practices so well discussed by Vance Packard are the logical result of maximizing a marketed physical flow. If we must maximize something it should be the stock of wealth, not the ecological limits that constrain this maximization.

But why this perverse emphasis on flows, this flow fetishism of standard economic theory? Again the underlying issue is distribution. There is no theoretical explanation, much less justification, for the distribution of the stock of wealth. It is a historical datum. But the distribution of the flow of income is at least partly explained by marginal productivity theory, which at times is even misinterpreted as a justification. Everyone gets a part of the flow—call it wages, interest, rent or profit—and it all looks rather fair. But not everyone owns a piece of the stock, and that does not seem quite so fair. Looking only at their flow helps to avoid disturbing thoughts.

But even if wants were infinite, and even if we redefine GNP to eliminate swelling, infinite wants cannot be satisfied by maximizing physical production. As people grow richer they will want more leisure. Physical growth cannot produce leisure. As physical productivity increases, leisure can be produced by working fewer hours to produce the same physical output. Even the common-sense argument for infinite wants—that the rich seem to enjoy their high consumption—cannot be generalized without committing the fallacy of composition. If all earned the same high income, a consumption limit occurs sooner than if only a minority had high incomes. The reason is that a large part of the consumption by plutocrats is consumption of personal and maintenance services rendered by the poor, which would not be available if everyone were rich. By hiring the poor to maintain and even purchase commodities for them, the rich devote their limited consumption time only to the most pleasurable aspects of consumption. The rich only ride their horses—they do not clean, comb, saddle, and feed them, nor do they clean the stables. If all did their own maintenance work, consumption would perforce be less. Time sets a limit.

The big difficulty with the infinite wants assumption, however, is pointed out by Keynes, who in spite of the use made of his theories in support of growth, was certainly no advocate of unlimited growth, as seen in the following quotation:

Now it is true that the needs of human beings seem to be insatiable. But they fall into two classes—those needs which are absolute in the sense that we feel them whatever the situation of our fellow human begins may be, and those which are relative in the sense that we feel them only if their satisfaction lifts us above, makes us feel superior to, our fellows. Needs of the second class, those which satisfy the desire for superiority, may indeed be insatiable; for the higher the general level, the higher still they are. But this is not so true of the absolute needs—a point may soon be reached, much sooner perhaps than we are all of us aware of, when those needs are satisfied in the sense that we prefer to devote our further energies to non-economic purposes.

Lumping these two categories together and speaking of infinite wants in general can only muddy the waters. The same distinction is implicit in Mill, who spoke despairingly of "consuming things which give little or no pleasure except as representative of wealth..."

The source of growth lies in the use made of surplus, the controllers of surplus may be a priesthood that controls physical idols made from the surplus and used to extract more surplus in the form of offerings and tribute. Or there may be feudal lords, who through the power given by possession of the land extract a surplus in the form of rent and the corvee. Or they may be capitalists (state or private) who use the surplus in the form of capital to gain more surplus in the form of interest and quasi-rents.

If growth must cease, the surplus becomes less important and so do those who control it. If the surplus is not to lead to growth, then it must be consumed, and ethical demands for equal surplus could not be countered by productivity arguments for inequality as necessary for accumulation. The surplus would eventually enter into the customary standard of living and cease to be recognized as a surplus. Accumulation in excess of depreciation, and the privileges attached thereto, would not exist.

We no longer speak of worshipping idols. Instead of idols we have an abomination called GNP, large parts of which, however, bear such revealing names as Apollo, Poseidon, and Zeus. Instead of worshipping the idol, we maximize it. The idol has become rather less concrete and material, while the mode of adoration has become technical rather than personal. But fundamentally, idolatry remains idolatry.

This article was excerpted from an article entitled "Toward a Stationary-State Economy," in Patient Earth, edited by John Harte and Robert Socolow. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, Inc., 1971.

A crisis sparked by the world's rich will have the poor paying the highest price


 

Our worries about jobs or pensions pale beside the fallout Africa and Asia now face in this absurdly skewed global system

A few weeks ago speculation began as to what might be the novels of the credit crunch. Where was the F Scott Fitzgerald, John Steinbeck or Martin Amis of 2008, the novelist who could speak to this crazily chaotic economic age? On cue last week, Aravind Adiga wins the Booker for The White Tiger. The critics have been sniffy, referring to him with discernible disdain as a former journalist. (He was Asia business correspondent for Time magazine.) But he won precisely because of his ringside seat at globalisation's boom years; he won because, despite its possible shortcomings as a novel, his book nails the myth of a benign US economic hegemony that has "lifted" millions out of poverty across Asia.
What it portrays in its place is horrific: a world where billions live in what Adiga's lead character describes as the "Darkness" - the abject poverty entrenched across swaths of rural and slum-city India. Meanwhile, an elite surfing on a tide of consumerism and cheap credit has been entirely dislocated from the majority of the country. This is a country where Bangalore's IT millionaires grow rich alongside an agrarian crisis characterised by an extraordinary phenomenon, the silent protests of 18,000 indebted farmers committing suicide every year - 200,000 in the past 12 years.
Just as Steinbeck stirred the conscience of America with his novels on the dust bowl and the Great Depression, and Charles Dickens challenged the complacencies of Victorian Britain, so Adiga reads as a blistering critique of an economic system that can only be described as grotesque. The Indian economist Jayati Ghosh points out that Mumbai has the second biggest sales globally of Mercedes cars, yet more than half of India lives in poverty without enough to eat.
The pertinence of Adiga's win is that India has been the poster boy for the past two decades of globalisation; Bono told me once that he dreamed of sub-Saharan Africa finding a way to emulate India's success. But its model of growth imported from the US was based on credit-fuelled consumerism for a fifth of the population while state investment in health, education, agriculture, infrastructure - crucial components of sustainable development - were cut back. Adiga's novel is a powerful volley in the crisis of legitimacy gripping the west's domination of the global economy.
Europe and the US have spent the weekend talking of reform of global capitalism and a Bretton Woods II, but they need to start with a grovelling apology. In recent decades, they have used their power through the IMF to write the rules and impose them across the world by ruthless manipulation and bullying. Belgium, Luxembourg and the Netherlands have together more votes in the IMF than China, India and Brazil.
In the past month, the US and Europe have been humiliated by the catastrophic failure of their own rules, and have been forced to rip them up. The double standards of western interests have been starkly exposed - their bail-outs are exactly what they have refused, repeatedly, to allow other countries to do in similar crises.
Those who will pay the heaviest price for the foolhardiness of deregulated financial capitalism are among those who are least responsible, as Brazil's President Lula angrily pointed out last week. The shockwaves of the west's banking crisis will shipwreck more vulnerable countries. In developing countries, people don't have the resources - welfare provision, savings, insurance - to tide them over a crisis. Instead, they go hungry, homeless - and they die. Across Africa and Asia, countries are bracing themselves for multiple hits, with falls in aid already threatened and a likely decline in the remittances that buoy up their economies - in the UK, the immigration minister Phil Woolas is already signalling a harder line on immigration. Fear of global recession is bringing commodity prices down and will reduce the demand for luxury products such as flowers, green beans and hot holidays. The anger among developing countries will spread. Our worries about jobs and pensions pale in comparison with the fallout on the billions who will not be able to feed or educate their children.
The western model of neoliberal financialisation was driven by clear self-interest, argues the Cambridge economist Ha-Joon Chang. The west couldn't compete in manufacturing (its labour costs are too high), so it turned to financial markets and used the cheapest way to make money: it offered loans, not for productive investment (factories, businesses) but to consumers, using their homes as collateral. Credit cards and small loans are particularly lucrative. So the west leaned heavily on countries through the World Trade Organisation and the IMF to open up their financial sectors. The western banks and the advertising companies piled in, and the result is a credit consumer boom. This may make a few people rich, but it is not, by any definition, development.
Chang, South Korean by background, saw the bullying graphically illustrated in the 1997-98 Asian financial crisis. Not only did the US and the IMF stop the Asian countries from implementing a state bail-out, they took advantage of the desperate situation to force South Korea and other Asian nations to adopt further financial deregulation. Productive investment in South Korea has since halved and credit has boomed. Now the country is on economists' critical list as its stockmarket plunges. Ironically, it is only the countries lucky enough to have dodged IMF bullying who are relatively safe in the current maelstrom: leftwing political groups in India closed ranks to protect its banking sector from the worst deregulation.
For most developing countries, the moral of the 1997-98 Asian crisis was that a primary purpose of financial management was to ensure sufficient capital reserves to avoid ever being vulnerable to the IMF thugs in their pinstripe suits. India, Korea, China: all have huge foreign reserves, often in US treasury bonds. It is the safest form of insurance in a global economy in which the flows of foreign exchange are so huge they can destroy a currency in of hours. But for a developing country to tie up most of its capital abroad is ruinously expensive; this capital should be invested in the country's own development - roads, for example, and schools to produce engineers, scientists and IT technicians.
Once again, who benefits from this absurdity of the global financial system? The west - in particular the US, whose current account deficit is funded by the sacrificed futures of millions across Asia. Chang's thesis, in his book Bad Samaritans - Guilty Secrets of Rich Nations and the Threat to Global Prosperity, is that the west has effectively kicked away the ladder that enabled it to achieve prosperity. It denies to developing countries the protection and the investment in industries that were essential to its own development.
At its most stark, the analysis is that the west has had a vested interest in keeping wage levels down in developing countries while making money from offering cheap credit. All it had to do was enlist a collaborating elite in each country to implement the deal, which was clearly not in the interests of the bulk of the population. Neoliberal globalisation was a system that ensured the rich got richer and the poor got poorer.


For the best free wallpapers from MSN Click here!

Sunday 19 October 2008

The 42 day victory hasn't won the war

 

 

But the government's attack on civil liberties is finally driving ordinary citizens to protest

Thirty years ago when I was irresponsible, full of beans and working for an evening newspaper there used to be a technique to divert the attention of the libel lawyer. The trick was to write a wholly outrageous allegation into the first few paragraphs of a story, then place the fact that you wanted to publish lower down. The libel lawyer would skid to a halt beside your desk clutching several sheets of copy - newspaper articles were then typed with three pieces of carbon paper and presented with one paragraph per page - and gibber that you could not call someone a glue-sniffing pederast in print. A tussle would ensue but after several minutes you would surrender the allegation. I lost count of the times my treasured fact got into print.
 
The government's tactics on the counter terrorism bill remind me of this - at least in effect. We know how much Jacqui Smith wanted 42-day detention without charge from her graceless capitulation in the Commons, but look at what remains in the bill and you will see that she's far from defeated. You may go further and reach the conclusion that in their claim to defend our free society the government, Home Secretary and the Home Office have become its greatest threat.
Still intact are the measures for post-charge questioning, which may add to the presumption of guilt; the confiscation of property without trial; extra punishment without trial beyond the original sentence; a new offence for volunteer workers of not giving police information; and a new offence of providing information about the armed forces.
 
This last measure was raised in a letter from Lord Rea, Sir Geoffrey Bindman and others to the Guardian in June: 'We fear this will become yet another convenient tool for use against the peace movement,' they said. Others believe that the bill's measures will, 'provide for the possibility of travel bans and long-term daily reporting or surveillance arrangements for anyone convicted of an offence under anti-terrorism legislation, without any regard for the seriousness of the offence'.
In other words we have still got one hell of a fight to preserve British liberty, and while there are many other serious calls on our attention these days we should pay attention to Ms Smith who towers over our democracy like some comic-strip super-villain dominatrix. She is wrong, corrosive and arrogant.
 
As Molière said: 'A woman always has her revenge ready.' Having been defeated by what for most was a heart-warming majority in the Lords she announced a draft bill for extended detention without trial that she said she would keep until a time of crisis when she could push it through Parliament without opposition. What does that say for her respect for the calm deliberations that defeated 42 days last week or the government's opportunistic use of the menace of terrorism?
 
The Home Secretary is remorseless. Last Wednesday she announced a typical New Labour consultation on the government's Interception Modernisation Programme that will gather and store the information from all emails, internet connections and phone calls. 'I want this (consultation),' she said, 'to be combined with well-informed debate, characterised by openness, rather than mere opinion, by reason and reasonableness.' I wonder how 'openness' trumps 'mere opinion' in her mind. At any rate it is clear 'reasonableness' in this context means going along with the government and giving up our freedoms, as we have been doing for 10 years now.
Let us just be clear that this new proposal represents a very great threat to individual privacy and in practice it is no different from the original idea of collecting the content of all emails and phone calls. 'The government is proposing to record - for life - the details of everyone you call or write to and what websites you visit,' said Phil Booth of NO2ID. Keith Vaz, chair of the Home Affairs select committee, Lord Carlisle, the government's independent reviewer of terror laws and the left-wing backbencher John McDonnell - none of them in the front rank of civil libertarians - all expressed grave alarm at this idea.
 
So did the Times and Daily Mail. So did the audience of BBC's Question Time: when Geoff Hoon, the new Secretary of State for Transport said he would go a long way to undermine civil liberties to stop people being killed by terrorists, the mockery of the audience, to say nothing of the guilt and irritation on Hoon's face, was palpable.
 
Two years ago I wondered in these pages when the penny would drop with the British public and the media about the attack on civil liberties. It is plainly beginning to. The public is worried about the shoddy laws the government tries to rush past them with its phony calls for consensus and reasonableness.
 
A small incident in Liverpool last week seemed to indicate something was happening. When police tried to break up a demonstration in support of the Freedom Not Fear organisation, it was passers-by who shouted, 'free speech' and 'you're a disgrace' as the police made arrests.
 
The change of attitudes has come about partly because of the government's appalling record on data security. Not a week goes by, it seems, without a security lapse. Last week the Armed Forces minister Bob Ainsworth was forced to admit that the Ministry of Defence has lost a hard drive which may contain the details of 1.7 million people. This follows the news that the Home Office has lost a mere 43 laptops and 93 cell phones in three years, that a memory stick containing records of 84,000 prisoners has gone missing and that the personal details of 18,000 NHS staff vanished in the post. When the government asks the public to trust it with their data the response is: 'Why the bloody hell should we?'
 
We have got a long way to go and that is due to the authoritarian habits that have become so deeply ingrained in government departments, principally in the Home Office. The worry must be that whatever the government, the Home Office rolls on with its own agenda, a state within a state bent on increasing the power of centralised authority.


Read amazing stories to your kids on Messenger Try it Now!

A golden age, and other things they wish they'd never said.

 

Mr Brown and Mr Cameron couldn't flatter financiers enough. Now they're scrambling to reposition themselves in a world of bust

When a politician claims that he always saw the storm on the horizon, it is often more informative to read what he was saying when the sun was still shining. Before I listened to the latest thoughts from Gordon Brown and David Cameron on the crisis of capitalism, I first reminded myself what they were saying before the boom went bust.
 
Let's start with Gordon Brown in June 2005 giving the Chancellor's annual speech to the City at the Mansion House. Addressing the bow-tied ranks of money-changers, he paid lavish homage to 'your unique innovative skills, your courage and steadfastness'. They had his personal thanks 'for the outstanding, the invaluable contribution you make to the prosperity of Britain'. Though even the financiers may have wondered what courage had to do with it, they clapped long and hard.
Having hosed them with adulation every time he visited the City, Gordon Brown surpassed himself when he returned in 2007 to deliver his final Mansion House speech as Chancellor before he moved into Number 10. 'A new world order has been created,' he proclaimed. Britain was 'a new world leader' thanks to 'your efforts, ingenuity and creativity'. He congratulated himself for 'resisting pressure' to toughen up regulation of their activities. Everyone needed to follow the City's 'great example', emulate this 'high value-added, talent-driven industry'. 'Britain needs more of the vigour, ingenuity and aspiration that you already demonstrate.' Thanks to their 'remarkable achievements', we had the huge privilege to live in 'an era that history will record as the beginning of a new Golden Age'.
 
Or, as it turns out, an era that history will record as ending in the Great Crash of 2008. Their 'ingenuity' engineered the most seismic financial crisis in 80 years. Their 'aspiration' has destroyed swaths of their own industry and the rest of the economy. Their 'vigour' is propelling us into recession. What he then hailed as a 'Golden Age', the Prime Minister now deplores as an 'Age of Irresponsibility'.
 
David Cameron has had some fun at the expense of the Prime Minister. Which might make you assume that the Tory leader had foreseen, as Gordon Brown had not, that it would all turn to dust. So here is Mr Cameron in June 2006, offering his thoughts on 'the new global economy'. He trumpeted 'the victory of capitalism, privatisation and liberalisation'. Not to be out-grovelled by Gordon Brown when talking about bankers, the Tory leader lauded the 'highly innovative' City as 'the biggest international finance centre in the world'. Mr Cameron happily noted that 'there are more than 550 international banks and 170 global securities houses in London', numbers that may now be subject to downward revision. The Cameron of this pre-bust vintage gave the credit for all that reckless - sorry, 'innovative' - trading to 'critical Conservative decisions' when the Tories were in government. It proved that 'light regulation' and 'low regulation' were 'keys to success'.
 
Just over a year ago, in September 2007, Mr Cameron made a speech at the London School Of Economics. The financial markets were already experiencing what was then politely termed 'turbulence', but the Tory leader chose to amplify his thesis about the ascendancy of unconstrained capitalism. In a section entitled 'The End Of Economic History?', he answered the question by declaring that: 'The debate is now settled.' 'Liberalism' had prevailed. The left's silly idea that markets required tight regulation had been thoroughly discredited. 'The result? The world economy more stable than for a generation.' He drizzled sycophancy on the heads of the bankers, drooling that 'our hugely sophisticated financial markets match funds with ideas better than ever before'. What a pity the casino got so sophisticated that it traded trillions of dollars of toxic bets that no one understood, including the gamblers themselves.
 
I could fill every column until Christmas with the foolish eulogising of the animal spirits of ungoverned markets by the Prime Minister and the Leader of the Opposition. I could probably fill this entire newspaper with embarrassing quotes from senior politicians about the erstwhile masters of the universe. A generation of leaders, here and in much of the rest of the world, fell under the thrall of high finance. The commanding heights of politics were surrendered to the bankers. Right-leaning politicians did so from ideological conviction, left-leaning politicians did so because they came to believe that it was the only way to power. The markets were allowed to set the rules for the politicians. Leaders couldn't tax wealth more than the markets were prepared to allow. They couldn't spend, borrow, intervene or regulate without the permission of the gods of the dealing rooms. When Bill Clinton was in the White House, he would rage about the way in which his presidency was dictated to by 'a bunch of fucking bond traders'. One of his senior aides, James Carville, joked: 'I used to think if there was reincarnation, I wanted to come back as the President or the Pope or a .400 baseball hitter. But now I want to come back as the bond market. You can intimidate everybody.'
 
This side of the Atlantic, Tony Blair and Gordon Brown took a short spoon to supper with the devil. He seemed such a seductive fellow when the financial sector was growing four times as fast as the rest of the economy. The credit boom kept house prices rising, shop tills ringing, tax revenues flowing, the country feeling prosperous and voting Labour. The financial alchemists of the City appeared to have invented a perpetual motion machine for producing cheap money. No one in government wanted to ask awkward questions about ballooning debt and obscene bonuses that incentivised ever more reckless bets. Mr Brown made his wildly hubristic claim to have abolished 'boom and bust'. In so much as the Tories raised an objection, it was that Labour was over-constraining the 'wealth creators' with bureaucratic red tape.
 
Vince Cable was alone when he wandered the battlements of the City of Gold crying his warning that it would all end in tears. That the Lib Dem has been proved utterly correct doesn't seem to be doing his party much good in the polls, but at least it has made him Britain's most popular politician.
Gordon Brown and David Cameron are meanwhile scrambling to reposition themselves for the world of the bust. The Prime Minister would prefer we forgot that drivel about a 'Golden Age' and look out those of his old speeches in which he argued for a global surveillance system of financial markets. Mr Cameron would be obliged if we'd pretend we hadn't heard him extolling the gamblers and concentrate on his more recent call for 'economic responsibility'.
 
The Prime Minister's strategy is to try to internationalise not just the solutions to this crisis, but also the culpability for it. He would have us blame those greedy bankers who were once his heroes and the America that he once so admired. Mr Cameron is conversely keen to localise the blame around the Prime Minister. The Tory party has been uncomfortable supporting the government and unnerved by the sight of Gordon Brown feted as some sort of superhero. The Tory leader has been reassuring worried colleagues: 'I will pin the tail on the donkey.' Hence his speech on Friday which broke the pseudo truce by heaping culpability on the Prime Minister.
 
This parochial blame game takes place in the context of a much more important global realignment of the balance of power between finance, government and the rest of society. The barons of capital have been devoured by their own excesses. Forced to go running to the state for help, large chunks of their firms now owned by the taxpayers they previously treated with contempt, the bankers are now the supplicants to the politicians. Humiliation has been visited not just on the individual chief executives and chairmen who have lost their jobs; an entire class has been discredited in voters' eyes. High finance will not vanish, but its numbers, glamour and power will shrink. Charles Leadbetter, always an insightful analyst, draws a useful comparison with what happened to the trades union leaders. Those barons grew over-mighty in the Sixties and Seventies until they met their nemesis in the shape of Margaret Thatcher. They are still with us, but they lost their ability to mesmerise politicians and intimidate everyone else. High finance has similarly been dethroned.
 
There is no appetite, beyond the denuded ranks of revolutionary socialists, for a command economy anything like the model so discredited by the experiment with the Soviet Union. Governments have taken over banks out of necessity not ideological conviction. But there has been a shift. The intellectual and political climate now favours those sceptical about the more exaggerated claims made for markets. George Bush has been forced to nationalise banks. It looks increasingly likely that he will be succeeded by Barack Obama governing with the help of big Democrat majorities in Congress. David Cameron, who as recently as his party conference was inviting us to regard him as the son of Thatcher, is now denouncing 'irresponsible capitalism'. Gordon Brown has rediscovered a purpose for his premiership and a potential legacy in the reform and regulation of global finance.
 
The full extent and shape of this power shift will take time to become clear. This much is already certain. Political leaders will not fawn before money as they once did. The era of uncritical awe for financiers is over. The epoch of blind faith in the market is done with. When our leaders go to the City in future, they will no longer take knee pads with them.


Read amazing stories to your kids on Messenger Try it Now!

Exchange rate movements as explained by dealers

 By Tiffany Hutcheson
1 Introduction

Theoretically, the value of a currency is determined by the economic fundamentals of its country, such as interest rates, inflation rates and national income. These fundamentals have an effect on trade and capital flows and hence the demand and supply of the currency. However, there have been many well-known episodes when real exchange rates have moved contrary to these fundamentals for lengthy periods of time (Krugman, 1989). Attempts using empirical models to test economic fundamentals as a basis for predicting exchange rate movements have not been very successful especially over the short run (Taylor, 1995). Furthermore, market practitioners have successfully developed and implemented profitable trading strategies, which do not rely on economic fundamentals. One reason for the poor performance of trading activities based on fundamental analysis could be the behaviour of practitioners trading in the foreign exchange market (Krugman, 1989). For example, some practitioners may trade tactically in a way that forces an exchange rate to move away from its fundamental value. These practitioners would then establish a currency position that becomes profitable once general market trading moves the exchange rate back towards its true value (Rankin, 1999).

To gather information on the factors influencing traders, dealers in the Australian foreign exchange market were asked to complete a questionnaire survey. Their responses can be used to gauge the degree to which economic fundamentals influence the trading behaviour of dealers and hence exchange rates. As the majority of currency trading occurs through dealers, they are an ideal group to survey (Carew and Slayter, 1994). In order for their trading to be profitable they need to pay attention to any factor or event they consider will influence exchange rates. Consequently their responses can be used to obtain information on the relative importance dealers place on various factors considered to influence exchange rates. This information will contribute to the continuing debate on exchange rate determination. It may identify areas other than those previously studied, such as purchasing power parity, which could be researched in order to provide additional explanations for exchange rate movements.

The survey also included questions on the market's trading environment, such as the use of electronic broking, bid-ask spread size and the degree of competition in the market. The dealers' responses to these questions were analysed in an earlier paper (Hutcheson, 2001).
The paper is organised as follows. The preparation of the survey questions and the collection of the survey data are discussed in part two. The impact of changing economic fundamentals on exchange rates is investigated in part three while the influence of non-fundamental factors, impact of economic announcements and predictability of exchange rate movements are analysed in parts four, five and six respectively. Part seven contains some concluding observations about the survey responses.

2 The Survey Data

Each of the institutions licensed by the Reserve Bank of Australia, as at 12th July 1999, to deal in foreign exchange received a copy of the survey. A high response rate was achieved with 39 of the 59 surveys mailed out being completed and returned (1). Consequently, the survey responses should be representative of the views of the majority of dealers trading in the market. As explained in an earlier paper on this survey, most of the survey respondents held senior positions in the foreign exchange section of their institution's treasury department (Hutcheson, 2001). The comprehensive knowledge and market experience of these respondents should ensure the survey responses are a fairly accurate description of events in the market.
Survey data has been used in the past to obtain feedback from foreign exchange dealers (2). Some of the questions used in this survey are based on questions included in surveys undertaken by Cheung, Chinn and Marsh (1999), Cheung and Wong (2000) and Cheung and Chinn (2001). However, the questions are asked in a different way to the other surveys. Consequently, it is difficult to directly compare the responses to all the similar questions across the surveys.

3 Fundamental Movements in Exchange Rate

Market participants known as fundamental analysts adopt the notion that exchange rate movements are determined by the economic fundamentals of the countries represented by the exchange rate. They argue that the market regards a currency, as being under or over valued if it does not reflect these fundamentals thus creating a profitable arbitrage opportunity. In a floating exchange rate regime, where central banks do not intervene, arbitrageurs would buy undervalued currencies and sell overvalued currencies. This trading would force the currency's value to move quickly back towards its true value (Neely, 1997). According to fundamentalists if all currently available information on economic fundamentals is correctly priced into an exchange rate it will only change when new information becomes available.

Regrettably daily and intra-day exchange rate movements are not well explained by fundamental analysis (Singleton, 1987). In fact there have been times when it has appeared as though dealers have simply disregarded economic fundamentals and are merely overreacting to news and rumours (Shleifer and Summers, 1990). As shown in table 1 the majority of respondents believe that intra-day exchange rate movements do not reflect changes in the fundamental value of an exchange rate. They feel that changing fundamental values are reflected a lot more in the movements that occur within a period of six months or greater. These responses reinforce the finding from other surveys that fundamental analysis became more important as the time horizon increased (Taylor and Allen, 1992; Cheung, Chinn and Marsh, 1999; Cheung and Wong, 2000; Cheung and Chinn, 2001).

4 Non-Fundamental Movements in Exchange Rate

The respondents indicate in Table 2 that excessive speculation and manipulation by hedge funds are the main factors preventing exchange rates from reflecting their fundamental value. Excessive intervention by central banks was the next most heavily supported factor while views taken by major trading banks and slowness of dealers to respond did not receive as much support. Whilst speculation has for some time been seen as a force that can potentially destabilise exchange rate movements, only in recent years have hedge funds been one of the factors held responsible for unpredicted swings in exchange rates.
Cheung and Wong's (2000) survey on dealers trading in Hong Kong, Tokyo and Singapore and Cheung and Chinn's (2001) survey on dealers trading in the United States also found that excessive speculation and hedge fund manipulation were regarded to be the major forces behind exchange rate movements.

4.1 Speculation

It has been argued that speculative forces can destabilise currencies and prevent them from reflecting a country's economic fundamentals (Neely, 1997). However, as shown in Table 3, the survey respondents do not unanimously support speculation as a destabilising force with 55.6% indicating that speculation mainly moves exchange rates towards their fundamental value while 44.4% indicate that it moves them away. This is consistent with the finding by Cheung and Wong (2000) for the Hong Kong, Tokyo and Singapore markets. On the other hand 70.67% of the respondents to Cheung and Chinn's (2001) survey of United States dealers considered speculation to be a force that moved exchange rates in the direction of their fundamental values.
The stabilising nature of speculation arises because speculators buy currencies whose value they expect to increase and sell currencies whose value they expect to decrease. When a currency's value moves in the expected direction the speculator will reverse their currency position and profit. As speculators reverse buying positions when exchange rates are increasing and reverse selling positions when exchange rates are decreasing, you would expect their trading to offset large upward and downward pressures on the value of a currency. However, there have been several speculative episodes since currencies began to be floated in the 1970s when excessive speculation has been blamed for driving exchange rates away from their true values. During these episodes exchange rates increased or decreased by more than was supported by economic fundamentals (Krugman, 1989). In particular the exchange rate movements did not support the relationships between exchange rates and changing relative inflation rates and interest rates between countries as explained by purchasing power parity and uncovered interest parity respectively. In other words it was the speculative trading that was causing the exchange rate to move rather than changing market fundamentals. Consequently, when speculators eventually reversed their position it was some time before exchange rates moved back towards their true value. Particularly if dealers who did not normally speculate started to imitate the trading behavior of speculators, a phenomenon known as herding behavior, without regard to whether or not their behavior is supported by economic fundamentals (Banerjee, 1992). It would take these dealers longer to reverse their positions than the large speculators and so exchange rates would continue to be driven away from their true value.

Excessive speculation has been one of several trading strategies adopted by a recently developed type of investment vehicle known as hedge funds. Hedge funds are typically made up of a group of wealthy investors who employ a manager to achieve the maximum return in particular asset classes. As managers are generously rewarded for their achievements, they can choose to adopt aggressive trading strategies (Chicago Mercantile Exchange, 1995). In foreign exchange markets hedge funds have been known to gradually build up very large positions in particular currencies and then reverse these positions rapidly. If their reversal generates excessive exchange rate movements they are able to earn large profits. By building up the positions gradually their impact on exchange rates is only really felt when they reverse their positions. However, only a small number of hedge funds are large enough to create market positions sizeable enough to generate such movements (Reserve Bank of Australia, 1999).

The survey respondents would have recently experienced the destabilising impact of hedge funds on the Australian dollar in mid 1998. Between December 1997 and March 1998 hedge funds were said to have built up large short positions in the Australian dollar using borrowed funds (Rankin, 1999). During this period the Australian dollar was already experiencing a downward trend following the unfavorable impact of the Asian crisis on Australia's trade and capital flows. Consequently, the effect of hedge funds selling the Australian dollar went largely unnoticed. However, as the Australian dollar approached US60 cents, hedge funds began to sell more aggressively and generated uncertainty among other currency traders about what exchange rate the Australian dollar should trade at (Rankin, 1999). Significant Reserve Bank intervention was required in early June 1998 to stop this aggressive selling from continuing (Reserve Bank Bulletin, 1998).
While the respondents do not unanimously support speculation as a stabilising force, most of them felt it increased exchange rate volatility and improved market efficiency and liquidity (see Table 3). The increased volatility can be partly explained by speculators adopting trading strategies differing from those of other market participants. That is they could be buying or selling currencies at a time when other market participants are trading in the opposite direction or not trading very actively. The ability for speculation to improve market efficiency can be accounted for by the tendency for speculators to commence trading when they perceive that current and expected market fundamentals have not been correctly priced into the existing exchange rates (Blundall-Wignall et al., 1993). They will then trade in a manner that forces a currency's value to change until it reaches its true value. This increase in efficiency could also be accompanied by increased market liquidity as previously inactive dealers and dealers who normally trade for other reasons will enter the market to profit from the impact of speculative trading on the exchange rate.

4.2 Intervention by the Reserve Bank

Central banks intervene in foreign exchange markets if they consider volatility to be excessive or currencies to be under or overvalued. In Australia the timing and size of the intervention undertaken by the Reserve Bank has varied across several periods since the Australian dollar was floated in December 1983 (Andrew and Broadbent, 1994). This variation has been due to a wide range of factors such as the severity of exchange rate volatility being experienced and how the intervention will affect other government policies. However, whatever the reason for the intervention most of the respondents feel that the Reserve Bank normally intervenes at the appropriate moment with only 14.3% feeling that its timing has been inappropriate (see Table 4). In recent years the Reserve Bank has seen the need to intervene several times. However, prior to 1997 the Reserve Bank had not intervened since November 1993.

72.7% of the respondents feel that Reserve Bank intervention has been successful in moving exchange rates towards their fundamental values. In fact, 76.55% of the respondents believe that Reserve Bank intervention achieves its goals. These responses support a study undertaken by Andrew and Broadbent (1994) on the effectiveness of Reserve Bank intervention. They argue that intervention will be successful if the Reserve Bank makes a profit from supporting a depreciating Australian dollar by buying at low exchange rate levels and an appreciating Australian dollar by selling at high exchange rates. Their study found that the Reserve Bank's foreign exchange operations had been profitable over most of the periods when intervention was taking place. While the Reserve Bank's trading on behalf of its clients, principally the Commonwealth Government, may have generated some of this profit, the continued finding of profitability over long periods does lend some support for judging intervention to be successful.

The respondents are equally divided on the impact of Reserve Bank intervention on volatility with 50% feeling it decreases volatility and 50% feeling it increases volatility. This appears to be contradictory to the notion that successful intervention should be stabilising. However, volatility is more likely to decrease over the long term, as successful intervention begins to calm down market behavior (Andrew and Broadbent, 1994). On the other hand intra-day volatility would increase when dealers did not correctly anticipate the intervention undertaken by the Reserve Bank, as they would now need to trade out of their current market positions.

5 Impact of Economic Announcements

Whilst the survey respondents maintain that changing economic fundamentals mainly have an impact on long-term exchange rate movements. Unexpected economic announcements made by governments can influence intra-day exchange rate movements. When determining a currency's value market participants will take into consideration the existing and expected economic fundamentals of the currency's country. So when government announcements of the actual fundamentals differ from market expectations, dealers will trade in a way that causes exchange rates to change, if dealers do not react before or at the same time as other dealers any profitable opportunity that exists will be traded away. Several studies using intra-day data have concluded that new economic announcements take only a few minutes to have an impact (Almeida et al., 1998; Kim, 1998). Table 5 reveals that dealers tend to react within less than a minute when announcements from the major developed countries on domestic inflation, unemployment, trade deficit, current account, interest rates, retail sales and gross domestic product differ from what was expected.

Several respondents claimed that in Australia the Australian dollar/United States dollar spot market reacted instantaneously to announcements by the Australian government whilst the reaction time in other spot market currency pairings was more delayed. The market also did not react as quickly to announcements made by countries other than Australia. This may be partly because the overseas announcements, such as announcements from the United States of America, are made while Australian financial markets, other than the market for foreign exchange, are closed. Consequently, foreign exchange dealers may not fully adjust their trading position until they see the response to the announcements from other Australian financial markets when they open the following day (Kim, 1998). For example, dealers may wait to see how the domestic market for interest rate securities responds to changes in overseas interest rates.

Respondents are asked to select the economic announcement from Australia and the United States of America that they consider has the biggest impact on the Australian foreign exchange market. Table 6 shows that five years ago respondents regarded interest rate announcements made by the Reserve Bank of Australia had the biggest impact followed by announcements on the current account, inflation and then trade balance. Today interest rate announcements still have the biggest impact but inflation and unemployment and then the current account and trade deficit now follow it. The strong support for interest rates announcements is expected as the direction and magnitude of international capital flows is affected by changes to relative interest rates between countries. A reason for dealers providing greater support for inflation announcements today than they did five years ago could be due to their growing concern about the ease in which the direction of international capital flows can change. The sudden capital reversals experienced by several Asian countries in the late 1990s made dealers aware of the speed in which the direction of these flows can change. As the Reserve Bank of Australia will place upward pressure on interest rates when inflation increases
above a target range, changing inflation can be seen as a factor influencing capital flows (Reserve Bank of Australia, 1996). Consequently, dealers expect international capital flows will be fairly responsive to announcements of higher inflation. There is still a close link between the current account and trade balance and the Australian dollar, as the majority of Australian exports are commodities priced in foreign currencies (Gruen and Kortian, 1996). Consequently, changes to world commodity prices affect export revenue and hence exchange rates.

Of the announcements covering economic conditions in the United States, the announcements that have the biggest impact on the Australian foreign exchange market today as well as five years ago are those for interest rates and employment. Current account and trade deficit announcements from the United States have very little impact, as they are not seen to be strong indicators of economic and financial conditions in the United States.

6 Predictability

The ability to successfully predict exchange rate movements has been questioned by both academics and dealers. In Table 7 the respondents give very little support for exchange rate movements being either always predictable or never being predictable. The majority of respondents felt that if anything they were more likely to be sometimes predictable. They give slightly more support for intra-day exchange rate movements being sometimes predictable than they do for periods of less than six months and periods longer than six months.
Although the respondents do not regard exchange rate movements as being very predictable, they do believe that several factors can be identified as having a major influence on exchange rates depending on the time horizon in question. In Table 8 respondents maintain that intra-day exchange rate movements are mainly determined by order placements followed by over-reaction to news, speculative forces, bandwagon effects and technical trading. The confidential nature of inter-dealer trades makes it very difficult to obtain data on the volume and price of individual trades. Consequently, the disclosure by respondents that order placements have a major influence on intra-day exchange rate movements indicates that studies of order flows should be able to reveal information on trading behavior.

However, as the time horizon increases the respondents indicate that economic fundamentals have a growing impact on exchange rate movements while the other factors become less significant, particularly over periods greater than six months. Order placements and over-reaction to news only seem to have an impact on intra-day exchange rate movements. Speculative forces and bandwagon effects, where dealers adopt the trading trends of other dealers, have the same degree of impact intra-day and over the medium run. Technical trading, which involves historical exchange rates being used to forecast future trends in exchange rate movements, has its greatest influence on medium run exchange rate movements. However, unlike economic fundamentals, technical trading has little impact on long-run exchange rate movements.

7 Conclusion

This paper analyses the responses provided by Australian foreign exchange dealers to a questionnaire survey on the factors influencing exchange rate movements and hence trading behavior. Dealers will have experienced periods when exchange rates movements were regarded as being normal as well as circumstances deemed to be irregular. Consequently, their responses to the survey questions should be able to provide information on the factors generating movements in exchange rates. While the dealers do differ in their responses to several of the survey questions, a majority response was recorded for most of the questions.

The survey respondents do agree with the theoretical argument that exchange rate movements can be explained by changing economic fundamentals. However, they believe this explanation holds mainly over the longer term. Although when announcements of Australian economic fundamentals are different from what the market expected, dealers are seen to react within less than a minute to correctly price the anomaly into current exchange rates. The economic announcement having the biggest impact both today and five years ago is interest rates.

Speculative behaviour is regarded to be the main factor that prevents exchange rates from reflecting their fundamental value. However, there was no unanimity among the respondents on whether or not speculation was a stabilising force. In fact speculation was seen to both increase exchange rate volatility and improve market efficiency. Excessive intervention by central banks also received considerable support as a factor behind non-fundamental exchange rate movements. Intervention by the Reserve Bank of Australia tends to successfully move exchange rates towards their fundamental value and is conducted at the most appropriate time, according to most respondents.

The respondents did not feel that speculative forces fully explained intra-day exchange rate movements. Factors considered to have a greater influence on moment-to-moment movements in exchange rates were order placements by clients and overreaction of market participants to events. Technical trading was considered to make an impression on medium term exchange movements.

Whilst this survey has been able to identify factors respondents believe influence exchange rate movements, it also found that most of the respondents do not feel that exchange rates can be accurately predicted. In fact they see exchange rate movements as being only sometimes predictable over all time horizons.