Search This Blog

Showing posts with label skewed. Show all posts
Showing posts with label skewed. Show all posts

Saturday, 15 July 2023

A Level Economics 7: Production Possibility Frontier

Discuss the connection between long-term economic growth, productivity changes, and shifts in an economy's PPFs. Explain how advancements in technology, increased efficiency, and investments in human capital can contribute to outward or skewed shifts in the PPFs. Provide relevant examples to support your explanation.


Long-term economic growth is closely linked to productivity changes, and these changes can lead to shifts in an economy's production possibility frontiers (PPFs). Advancements in technology, increased efficiency, and investments in human capital play crucial roles in driving productivity growth, which can result in outward or skewed shifts in the PPFs.

  1. Advancements in Technology: Technological progress is a key driver of long-term economic growth. Innovations, new inventions, and the adoption of advanced technologies can significantly enhance productivity by improving the efficiency of production processes. For example, the invention of the steam engine during the Industrial Revolution revolutionized manufacturing and transportation, leading to an outward shift in the PPFs of countries that embraced this technology.

  2. Increased Efficiency: Improving efficiency in resource allocation and production methods can also drive long-term economic growth and shift the PPFs outward. Efficiency gains can arise from factors such as process improvements, better management practices, and specialization. For instance, if a country implements streamlined supply chains, adopts lean production techniques, or optimizes resource allocation, it can produce more output with the same amount of resources, resulting in an outward shift in the PPFs.

  3. Investments in Human Capital: Human capital refers to the skills, knowledge, and capabilities of the workforce. Investments in education, training, and health contribute to the growth of human capital, leading to higher productivity levels. An educated and skilled workforce can employ advanced technologies, adapt to changing market demands, and drive innovation. For example, countries that invest in quality education and provide opportunities for lifelong learning can experience significant productivity growth, which translates into an outward shift in the PPFs.

These factors, advancements in technology, increased efficiency, and investments in human capital, can contribute to both outward and skewed shifts in the PPFs. An outward shift represents an expansion in an economy's production possibilities, allowing for increased output levels of existing goods and services or the production of new goods and services. Skewed shifts occur when there is a disproportionate improvement in the production capabilities of one good relative to another, reflecting changes in comparative advantage due to factors like specialization or resource availability.

For instance, let's consider an economy that heavily invests in renewable energy technology and implements policies to promote clean energy production. As a result, the economy experiences a significant increase in the productivity and efficiency of renewable energy production. This leads to an outward shift in the PPF, enabling the economy to produce more renewable energy while maintaining or even reducing the production of traditional fossil fuel-based energy.

In summary, long-term economic growth is intertwined with productivity changes, and advancements in technology, increased efficiency, and investments in human capital are key drivers of productivity growth. These factors can contribute to outward or skewed shifts in an economy's PPF.

Friday, 21 April 2017

Why I want to see private schools abolished

Tim Lott in The Guardian

I am inclined towards equality of opportunity for all children. I am also aware that such a phrase is open to multiple definitions – and with most of them, such equality verges on the impossible. For instance, we can all hold up our hands in pious disapproval at the unfairness of, say, familial nepotism – such as that seen among Donald Trump’s brood – yet most of us are not much better. Anyone who is educated, or from a middle-class background is also operating on a manifestly unequal playing field.
This is largely because of the workings of social capital – of which nepotism is simply an extreme example. At a mundane level, it means having parents who are educated, interested in education, connected within the professions and happy to use those connections – what you might call cultural nepotism. I am not innocent of this. Conscience takes a fall when one’s children are involved.
This kind of inequality is difficult to legislate against. The divide between rich and poor families is growing, and largely inescapable. A new report from the Institute for Public Policy Research thinktank shows that the number of internships has risen 50% since 2010 – another leg-up for those who can afford to take low-paid or unpaid positions.

Add in decent housing, good nutrition and the imparting of confidence and the middle classes have a huge advantage, even before you talk about schooling. There are other ineradicable forms of inequality – genetic capital for instance, since intelligence, is, according to most scientific sources, at least 50% hereditary. But social capital is the most visible.


Middle-class kids will, on aggregate, still come out on top because of their pre-existing advantages

This entrenched and inevitable advantage is, perversely, why I oppose private schools far more firmly than grammar schools (which, at least in theory, could be meritocratic). It is not that I hope to take away from privileged children any unfair head start. I just want to take away the only advantage that is purely down to money and entirely subject to legislation.
Private schools add insult to injury. If you get rid of them and shift all the pupils into the state system, nothing will guarantee the latter’s improvement with more certainty. And the middle-class kids will, on aggregate, still come out on top because of their pre-existing advantages – so it is especially egregious that so many people so staunchly oppose their abolition.

Grammar schools, as envisaged in the 1944 Education Act (with selection based not solely on tests but also on aptitude and past performance) might be the answer to those who suggest the abolition of private schools would result in “dumbing down” – as long as they were a resource for the clever and motivated rather than the privileged and tutored. There would still be inequality, but it would be minimised. Absolutely level playing fields are, and always will be, a myth. However, we can make the fields less ridiculously skewed than they are at the moment.

It is doable, practically. Shame that it just appears impossible to do politically. The fact that Jeremy Corbyn is suggesting charging private schools VAT is a step in the right direction. A few more steps in that direction and he might establish a policy that would make me vote for him.

But I’ll take a (state-educated) guess that it won’t happen. There are too many people with too many fingers in the private-schooling pie – among them a fair number of Corbyn’s shadow cabinet. Because when those who stand against inequality simultaneously take advantage of it, their motivation is sorely undermined – whether or not it would be a vote winner.

Such is the insidiousness of educational inequality – so long as it works for the policy-makers themselves, it has little or no chance of real reform. Those responsible can always tell themselves that it’s just for their children’s sake. It is understandable. It may even be forgivable. But it is a total cop-out.