Ian Stewart in The Observer 21-02-12
It was the holy grail of investors. The Black-Scholes equation,
brainchild of economists Fischer Black and Myron Scholes, provided a
rational way to price a financial contract when it still had time to
run. It was like buying or selling a bet on a horse, halfway through the
race. It opened up a new world of ever more complex investments,
blossoming into a gigantic global industry. But when the sub-prime
mortgage market turned sour, the darling of the financial markets became
the Black Hole equation, sucking money out of the universe in an
unending stream.
Anyone who has followed the crisis will understand that the real
economy of businesses and commodities is being upstaged by complicated
financial instruments known as derivatives. These are not money or
goods. They are investments in investments, bets about bets. Derivatives
created a booming global economy, but they also led to turbulent
markets, the credit crunch,
the near collapse of the banking system and the economic slump. And it
was the Black-Scholes equation that opened up the world of derivatives.
The
equation itself wasn't the real problem. It was useful, it was precise,
and its limitations were clearly stated. It provided an
industry-standard method to assess the likely value of a financial
derivative. So derivatives could be traded before they matured. The
formula was fine if you used it sensibly and abandoned it when market
conditions weren't appropriate. The trouble was its potential for abuse.
It allowed derivatives to become commodities that could be traded in
their own right. The financial sector called it the Midas Formula and
saw it as a recipe for making everything turn to gold. But the markets
forgot how the story of King Midas ended.
Black-Scholes
underpinned massive economic growth. By 2007, the international
financial system was trading derivatives valued at one quadrillion
dollars per year. This is 10 times the total worth, adjusted for
inflation, of all products made by the world's manufacturing industries
over the last century. The downside was the invention of ever-more
complex financial instruments whose value and risk were increasingly
opaque. So companies hired mathematically talented analysts to develop
similar formulas, telling them how much those new instruments were worth
and how risky they were. Then, disastrously, they forgot to ask how
reliable the answers would be if market conditions changed.
Black
and Scholes invented their equation in 1973; Robert Merton supplied
extra justification soon after. It applies to the simplest and oldest
derivatives: options. There are two main kinds. A put option gives its
buyer the right to sell a commodity at a specified time for an agreed
price. A call option is similar, but it confers the right to buy instead
of sell. The equation provides a systematic way to calculate the value
of an option before it matures. Then the option can be sold at any time.
The equation was so effective that it won Merton and Scholes the 1997
Nobel prize in economics. (Black had died by then, so he was
ineligible.)
If everyone knows the correct value of a derivative
and they all agree, how can anyone make money? The formula requires the
user to estimate several numerical quantities. But the main way to make
money on derivatives is to win your bet – to buy a derivative that can
later be sold at a higher price, or matures with a higher value than
predicted. The winners get their profit from the losers. In any given
year, between 75% and 90% of all options traders lose money. The world's
banks lost hundreds of billions when the sub-prime mortgage bubble
burst. In the ensuing panic, taxpayers were forced to pick up the bill,
but that was politics, not mathematical economics.
The
Black-Scholes equation relates the recommended price of the option to
four other quantities. Three can be measured directly: time, the price
of the asset upon which the option is secured and the risk-free interest
rate. This is the theoretical interest that could be earned by an
investment with zero risk, such as government bonds. The fourth quantity
is the volatility of the asset. This is a measure of how erratically
its market value changes. The equation assumes that the asset's
volatility remains the same for the lifetime of the option, which need
not be correct. Volatility can be estimated by statistical analysis of
price movements but it can't be measured in a precise, foolproof way,
and estimates may not match reality.
The idea behind many
financial models goes back to Louis Bachelier in 1900, who suggested
that fluctuations of the stock market can be modelled by a random
process known as Brownian motion. At each instant, the price of a stock
either increases or decreases, and the model assumes fixed probabilities
for these events. They may be equally likely, or one may be more
probable than the other. It's like someone standing on a street and
repeatedly tossing a coin to decide whether to move a small step
forwards or backwards, so they zigzag back and forth erratically. Their
position corresponds to the price of the stock, moving up or down at
random. The most important statistical features of Brownian motion are
its mean and its standard deviation. The mean is the short-term average
price, which typically drifts in a specific direction, up or down
depending on where the market thinks the stock is going. The standard
deviation can be thought of as the average amount by which the price
differs from the mean, calculated using a standard statistical formula.
For stock prices this is called volatility, and it measures how
erratically the price fluctuates. On a graph of price against time,
volatility corresponds to how jagged the zigzag movements look.
Black-Scholes
implements Bachelier's vision. It does not give the value of the option
(the price at which it should be sold or bought) directly. It is what
mathematicians call a partial differential equation, expressing the rate
of change of the price in terms of the rates at which various other
quantities are changing. Fortunately, the equation can be solved to
provide a specific formula for the value of a put option, with a similar
formula for call options.
The early success of Black-Scholes
encouraged the financial sector to develop a host of related equations
aimed at different financial instruments. Conventional banks could use
these equations to justify loans and trades and assess the likely
profits, always keeping an eye open for potential trouble. But less
conventional businesses weren't so cautious. Soon, the banks followed
them into increasingly speculative ventures.
Any mathematical
model of reality relies on simplifications and assumptions. The
Black-Scholes equation was based on arbitrage pricing theory, in which
both drift and volatility are constant. This assumption is common in
financial theory, but it is often false for real markets. The equation
also assumes that there are no transaction costs, no limits on
short-selling and that money can always be lent and borrowed at a known,
fixed, risk-free interest rate. Again, reality is often very different.
When
these assumptions are valid, risk is usually low, because large stock
market fluctuations should be extremely rare. But on 19 October 1987,
Black Monday, the world's stock markets lost more than 20% of their
value within a few hours. An event this extreme is virtually impossible
under the model's assumptions. In his bestseller The Black Swan, Nassim Nicholas Taleb, an expert in mathematical finance, calls extreme events of this kind black swans.
In ancient times, all known swans were white and "black swan" was
widely used in the same way we now refer to a flying pig. But in 1697,
the Dutch explorer Willem de Vlamingh found masses of black swans on
what became known as the Swan River in Australia. So the phrase now
refers to an assumption that appears to be grounded in fact, but might
at any moment turn out to be wildly mistaken.
Large fluctuations
in the stock market are far more common than Brownian motion predicts.
The reason is unrealistic assumptions – ignoring potential black swans.
But usually the model performed very well, so as time passed and
confidence grew, many bankers and traders forgot the model had
limitations. They used the equation as a kind of talisman, a bit of
mathematical magic to protect them against criticism if anything went
wrong.
Banks, hedge funds, and other speculators were soon trading complicated derivatives such as credit default swaps
– likened to insuring your neighbour's house against fire – in
eye-watering quantities. They were priced and considered to be assets in
their own right. That meant they could be used as security for other
purchases. As everything got more complicated, the models used to assess
value and risk deviated ever further from reality. Somewhere underneath
it all was real property, and the markets assumed that property values
would keep rising for ever, making these investments risk-free.
The
Black-Scholes equation has its roots in mathematical physics, where
quantities are infinitely divisible, time flows continuously and
variables change smoothly. Such models may not be appropriate to the
world of finance. Traditional mathematical economics doesn't always
match reality, either, and when it fails, it fails badly. Physicists,
mathematicians and economists are therefore looking for better models.
At the forefront of these efforts is complexity science, a new branch of mathematics
that models the market as a collection of individuals interacting
according to specified rules. These models reveal the damaging effects
of the herd instinct: market traders copy other market traders.
Virtually every financial crisis
in the last century has been pushed over the edge by the herd instinct.
It makes everything go belly-up at the same time. If engineers took
that attitude, and one bridge in the world fell down, so would all the
others.
By studying ecological systems, it can be shown that
instability is common in economic models, mainly because of the poor
design of the financial system. The facility to transfer billions at the
click of a mouse may allow ever-quicker profits, but it also makes
shocks propagate faster.
Was an equation to blame for the
financial crash, then? Yes and no. Black-Scholes may have contributed to
the crash, but only because it was abused. In any case, the equation
was just one ingredient in a rich stew of financial irresponsibility,
political ineptitude, perverse incentives and lax regulation.
Despite
its supposed expertise, the financial sector performs no better than
random guesswork. The stock market has spent 20 years going nowhere. The
system is too complex to be run on error-strewn hunches and gut
feelings, but current mathematical models don't represent reality
adequately. The entire system is poorly understood and dangerously
unstable. The world economy desperately needs a radical overhaul and
that requires more mathematics, not less. It may be rocket science, but
magic it's not.
Ian Stewart is emeritus professor of mathematics at the University of Warwick.
No comments:
Post a Comment