Search This Blog

Wednesday 18 March 2009

The market is destructive. That's its point


 

 

Brown and Obama declare they love free trade. So why don't they follow the logic of their thinking?

Governments must not respond to the financial crisis by erecting barriers to international trade. They must not adopt the "beggar thy neighbour" policies that deepened and prolonged the Great Depression of the 1930s.
 
So say most commentators and many politicians, including Peter Mandelson on these pages on Monday. Even President Obama, having advocated trade barriers during the Democratic primaries, now claims that he does not want to "send a protectionist signal". And Gordon Brown rarely misses an opportunity to recommend free trade in these troubled times.
 
They are confused. To see why, start by asking what is so good about free trade. The short answer is that it allocates resources to their most efficient uses. Any introductory economics textbook will explain how. But a simpler route to the answer is to see that international trade benefits us in the same way that technological advances do, as the economist Steven Landsburg explains with a fable (from his More Sex is Safer Sex: the Unconventional Wisdom of Economics): "Once there was a man who invented a new and cheaper way to analyse MRI data. Medical costs fell and more people got better care. The invention put some radiologists out of work, but even that had its upside - after a little retraining, the radiologists moved into other specialties where their talents were much appreciated.
 
"But one day, an investigative journalist tracked down the inventor's disgruntled former assistant and learnt that the great 'invention' was nothing more than a $600 laptop computer connected to the internet. The so-called inventor e-mailed data to Asia, where it was analysed by low-paid Asian radiologists. They e-mailed back their reports, which he advertised as the output from his machine."
 
Be it new technology or simply trade, the economic benefit of the new process is the same: cheaper medical care and, hence, resources liberated for other uses. And, be it technology or trade, these benefits could be eliminated by a subsidy to domestic radiologists. Suppose the analysis of an MRI scan costs $50 using the Asian radiologists and $100 using domestic radiologists. If government decided to subsidise domestic radiologists by $60 per MRI scan, then they could offer their services for $40 and patients would no longer prefer the Asian alternative.
 
The subsidy would not reduce the cost of domestic radiologists; their MRI analyses would still cost $100 to produce. The subsidy would thus divert resources away from their more efficient use. In other words, it would create waste. Since the wasted resources would no longer be available for alternative uses, the subsidy would make us poorer.
 
That is the reasoning of those of us who love free trade - or, at least, of most of us. It cannot be the reasoning of Mr Obama and Mr Brown. For, besides declaring their love of free trade, they declare their love of subsidies. They claim they can make us richer by maintaining the subsidies they already have in place - of agriculture and healthcare, to name but two of countless examples - and by adding subsidies for other industries as well, such as construction and car manufacturing.
 
Those who think subsidies will enrich us doubt the merits of the market mechanism. They doubt that market prices result in an efficient allocation of resources and they doubt the value of what the sociologist Joseph Schumpeter dubbed "creative destruction". They believe that the cost to those who lose their jobs or businesses as a result of competition exceeds the benefits to society provided by more efficient production. Economic planners - using subsidies, taxes, quotas, regulations and so on - can, they think, achieve better results than free markets.
 
Never mind which view is right. The question is which view Mr Obama and Mr Brown endorse. The contradiction in their pro-subsidy, pro-free trade position lies not merely in the inconsistent theoretical foundations of these two positions. It is more direct. As the MRI fable illustrated, domestic subsidies are themselves barriers to free trade. Mr Brown's subsidy of British carmakers (if only for "green" cars), creates a barrier to the import of more efficiently produced foreign cars.
 
It is fascinating, if futile, to speculate on the source of our leaders' incoherence. I suspect it comes from a superficial, pick-and-mix dedication to doing "what works". They have heard that trade barriers aggravated the Great Depression and also heard that Roosevelt's public works programme helped to return America to growth. So they plump for both subsidies and free trade, failing to think hard enough about how these policies are supposed to work to notice that their combination is impossible, not just intellectually but practically.
 
Mr Brown has long advocated impossible combinations, such as increasing both labour market flexibility and employee protection (just one of the miracles that he and Tony Blair promised their Third Way would deliver). But it is disappointing to discover that, after emerging from the fog of grandiose rhetoric, Mr Obama has the same tendency.
 
Jamie Whyte is the author of Bad Thoughts: A Guide to Clear Thinking
 

 

Glen is completely wrong. The standard of living would rise marginally in the UK and dramatically in Asia. And wages do not tend to a global average, they rise overall because money and resources including labour are not being wasted but are being allocated efficiently.

As has been happening.

 

Alan Wilkinson, Russell, New Zealand

 

That's fine as long as you accept that wages and standards of living will initially at least tend to some sort of global average. The standard of living in the UK would drop dramatically and that in Asia would rise marginally. I for one am not so altruistic.

 

Glen, Melbourne,

 

 

I suspect the main idea of loudly promoting free trade is to try to persuade other markets to stay open and non-protectionist rather than a serious declaration of personal intent. The reasoning would thus appear to be political rather than economic.



Windows Live Messenger just got better. Find out more!

Monday 16 March 2009

The logic of arranged marriage in India


 

The logic of arranged marriage in India

15 Mar 2009, 2226 hrs IST, Santosh Desai


Why does the institution of the arranged marriage survive in India in this day and age? The India I am talking about in this case includes the educated middle class, where the incidence of arranged marriages continues to be high and more importantly, is accepted without any difficulty as a legitimate way of finding a mate. Twenty years ago, looking at the future, one would have imagined that by now, the numbers of the arranged marriage types would have shrunk and the few remaining stragglers would be looked down upon as belonging to a somewhat primitive tribe. But this is far from being so.

The answer lies partly in the elastic nature of this institution, and indeed most traditional Indian customs, that allows it to expand its definition to accommodate the needs of modernity. So today's arranged marriage places individual will at the heart of the process; young men and women are rarely forced to marry someone against their wishes. The role of the parents has moved to that of being presiding deities, with one hand raised in blessing and the other hand immersed purposefully in the wallet.

The need for some arrangement when it comes to marriage is a very real one, both here as well as in those cultures where arranged marriages are anathema. The blind date, being set up by friends, online dating, the speed date, reality swayamvar-type shows are all attempts to arrange ways that one can meet a potential spouse. Here the idea of love is being not-so-gently manufactured by contriving a spark that could turn into the cozy fire of domesticity.

The arranged marriage of today is more clearly manufactured but it also offers a more certain outcome. Online matrimonial sites are full of young professionals seeking matches on their own, knowing that what is on the table here is not a date but the promise of marriage. In the West, the curiously antiquated notion that it is the prerogative of the man to propose marriage makes for a situation where the promise of marriage is tantalizingly withheld by one of the concerned parties for an indefinite period of time. Indeed, going by Hollywood movies, it would appear that to mention marriage too early in a relationship is a sure way of scaring off the man. So we have a situation where marriage is a mirage that shimmers on the horizon frequently, but materializes rarely. The mating process becomes a serial hunt with the man doing the pursuing to begin a relationship and the woman taking over the role in trying to convert it into something more lasting.

At a more fundamental level, the idea that romantic love is the most suitable basis for a long-term relationship is not as automatic as it might appear. Marriage is the only significant kinship tie that we enter into by choice. We don't choose our parents, our relatives or our children — these are cards that are dealt out to us. For a long time, in a lot of cultures, and even now in some, marriage too is a relationship we do not personally control. This view of marriage works best in contexts where the idea of the individual is not fully developed. People live in a sticky collective and individuality is blurred. A young Saraswat Brahmin boy, earning in four figures was sufficient as a description and one such person was broadly substitutable with another.

As the role of the individual increases and as dimensions of individuality get fleshed out in ever newer ways, marriage must account for these changes. The idea of romance makes the coming together of individuals seem like a natural event. Mutual attraction melts individuals together into a union. In contexts where communities fragment and finding mates as a task devolves to individuals, romance becomes a natural agent of marriage. The trouble is that while the device works very well in bringing people together, it is not intrinsically equipped to handle these individuals over time. For, the greater emphasis on the individual has also meant that personal needs and personal growth come to occupy a privileged position in every individual's life. Falling in love becomes infinitely easier than staying in it as individuals are no longer defined primarily by the roles they play in marriage.

So we have a situation where people fall in and out of love more often, making the idea of romance as a basis of marriage not as socially productive as it used to be. Romantic love seeks to extend the present while the arranged marriage aims at securing the future. It keeps the headiness of romance at bay, and recognizes that romance and the sustenance of a socially constructed long-term contract like marriage do not necessarily converge. Of course, the arranged marriage has its own assumptions about what variables make this contract work and these too offer no guarantees.

In a world where our present has become a poor indicator of our future, the idea of arranging marriages continues to hold charm. Whether it is cloaked in tradition as it is in India or in modernity as it is elsewhere, the institution of marriage needs some help. The expanded Indian view of the arranged marriage functions as a facilitated marriage search designed for individuals. Perhaps that is why convented matches from status families will continue to look for decent marriages, caste no bar.



Windows Live Hotmail just got better. Find out more!

Saturday 14 March 2009

Without fear, Viru’s come into his own

Harsha Bhogle
Posted online: Mar 13, 2009 at 0948 hrs
It would be easy to image Virender Sehwag as a pirate, terrifying genteel passengers on a cruise liner with his weapons and his audacity. Picture the bandana, the cutlass coming down with the speed of a bat clobbering a ball past mid-on! Pity then that he has the look of a genial halwai from Chandni Chowk, chubby cheeks and an enduring tussle with his girth, enjoying his jalebis as much as he does serving them; never too far from a smile and, as we now know, from the odd wink as well!
New Zealand’s bowlers might think he is a bully, riding roughshod over them and trivialising their offerings. But he isn’t a bully either because all bullies are, inherently, cowards shying away when someone bigger comes along. Over the last eight years, Sehwag has taken on the quickest in demanding circumstances and sometimes he has won and sometimes he has lost. But he is willing to take on the bowlers and the conditions, not afraid to lose, and that is not a quality bullies possess!

There is a secret to his fearlessness, a trait that resides in all those who are happy to live with risk; or indeed risk as most of us perceive it. Sehwag is not afraid of getting out. It doesn’t mean he is lackadaisical or that batting is a reckless, momentary pursuit. It is just that his mind is free from the fear of defeat.

And as most of us would have seen in our own lives, the moment we contemplate defeat, we open our doors to it. I’m sure he is aware, like most of us are, that in the pursuit of success, failure is always a neighbour, a by-stander waiting to jump in. But the more we look sideways at this neighbour, the less we look ahead. Sehwag has this extraordinary ability to let failure jump in from time to time but not worry too much about it.

But then, he has always been like this. What explains this amazing burst, this transformation from a potentially great but terribly ordinary one-day batsman to one that bowlers around the world fear and who, in his last 20 games, averages 60 with a strike rate of 130? For years Sehwag was a huge under-achiever, averaging a mere 30 at the top of the order and possessed of a maddening urge to find the fielder at third man to a ball that was short and outside off stump. Now he hardly seems to get out there and surely it cannot be because bowlers have stopped bouncing it short and high outside his off stump? Is speed, or lack of it, the issue, or are bowlers indeed bowling fuller or is there a greater discretion in strokeplay?

My guess is that he now has a greater variety of shots, especially on the leg side. He always flicked the ball well off his pads but could be kept quiet by the ball that bounced into his rib cage. Now he seems to have a couple of shots for balls in that area. First, the trademark straight jab through mid-wicket, a shot achieved through his incredible bat speed. But more important, when it gets higher, he has started pulling the short ball. And anything that comes off the middle of the bat and achieves decent elevation goes out of the ground in New Zealand anyway!

I also suspect he is being given the space that every performer needs. Inherently, performers need to be happy souls; a trapeze artist worrying about his job will probably find the safety net. With Gambhir, Yuvraj and Raina batting well, Dhoni solid and reliable and Tendulkar still evergreen, Sehwag probably has the licence to play his brand of fearless cricket. And he seems to be carrying this freedom with a touch of gravity because it can be a thin line between bravery and recklessness. For Sehwag to find out how far his ability can take him, he must have the freedom to play in his style and this team, through its composition and attitude, is giving him this freedom.

And so Sehwag can embellish our game with his own brand of cricket; so different from the two greats of this era — Rahul Dravid and Sachin Tendulkar. Dravid is the kind who would study angles like a draftsman, work out the best ones to employ and then use his incredible work ethic to perfect them. Tendulkar, for all his genius, has never been independent of the field setting; either showing up gaps through his placement or creating them where he wants to by playing the ball elsewhere (see how he plays the paddle sweep which forces a fielder to be placed there and opens up a gap where he wants it to be opened).

But Sehwag looks upon the field placement as an independent event; something the opposition captain has to do but not anything he needs to worry about.

That is why it is a great game; because it has room for all kinds; and because it has room for Sehwag.

‘Beginning of the end of tax havens’


 

 

By Vanessa Houlder
Published: March 13 2009 18:55 | Last updated: March 13 2009 18:55
 
A cascade of concessions on tax secrecy by some of the world's leading private wealth centres has been hailed as a breakthrough in a decade-long international assault on evasion.
 
Gordon Brown, British prime minister, talked on Friday about "the beginning of the end of tax havens".
 
The pursuit of tax evaders by foreign countries will be made easier by the promises of greater co-operation by Switzerland, Austria, Luxembourg, Hong Kong, Singapore, Liechtenstein, Andorra and others. They have bowed to pressure by adopting international standards on transparency, although insisting they will continue to protect investors' privacy.
 
Richard Hay of Stikeman Elliott, an international law firm, said: "Switzerland's capitulation to the OECD is a game-changer."
The anti-tax haven initiative led by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development has been stymied by charges of hypocrisy. The tiny islands and states accused of harbouring undeclared money deflected attacks by pointing out that similar charges could be levelled at OECD member states such as Switzerland as well as Asian financial centres such as Hong Kong and Singapore.
 
Concessions by big players such as Switzerland and Singapore rip that defence away from the remaining offshore centres such as Panama that cling to secrecy. They also dilute the threat that the closure of one haven will simply divert money to another.
The moves pave the way for intense pressure to be applied to the remaining hold-outs. Angel GurrĂ­a, secretary-general of the OECD, noted that "many jurisdictions still maintain arrangements that prevent them from assisting foreign authorities in tax investigations". Offshore centres reluctant to co-operate with foreign tax authorities face the threat of being "blacklisted" at next month's London summit. Sanctions ranging from higher withholding taxes to restricting banking transactions could be applied.
 
But critics of tax havens are sceptical about the OECD's initiative. Foreign tax authorities wanting to take advantage of tax information exchange agreements need to supply evidence of their suspicions. If they have no "smoking gun", they will be unable to extract information. More-over, the bilateral deals on information exchange rarely help developing countries chase down evaders. Oxfam, the charity, said this week that losses from offshore evasion may cost developing countries more than they receive in foreign aid.
 
Bankers and lawyers in the finance centres affected by this month's announcements have been keen to emphasise the limits to the concessions. Jean Schaffner, a Luxembourg partner of Allen & Overy, said the state's proposals were a "good compromise between the need to co-operate with foreign tax administrations and the desire to preserve privacy". Fears that foreign authorities could make "blanket requests" for information were not realised.
 
Moreover the crackdown on evasion does not tackle complex issues concerning corporate use of offshore centres, which companies often favour for their tax-neutrality and legal structure. The US administration has promised action against avoidance by US companies using tax havens.
 
Offshore centres are also anxiously eyeing anti-tax haven bills introduced in both US Houses of Congress last week, which were endorsed by Timothy Geithner, Treasury secretary, who promised "a much more ambitious effort to deal with offshore tax havens".
The legislation listed 34 "secrecy jurisdictions", although there was provision for jurisdictions to be removed if they have "information exchange practices that effectively overcome those secrecy barriers".
 
Offshore centres are also braced for a new attempt by the European Commission to close loopholes in the Savings Directive, its 2005 anti-evasion legislation. The Commission is keen to extend its geographic reach to ensure that evaders do not simply shift their money to centres such as Hong Kong, Singapore and Dubai.
 
Some offshore centres said they hoped that the political furore over tax havens before next month's G20 meeting might die down. Geoff Cook of Jersey Finance, which represents Jersey's finance industry said the concessions: "will defuse it to a large degree." But some influential politicians were guarded about the impact of the concessions.
 
Christine Lagarde, French finance minister, warned that "the devil is in the detail". She said: "We must go all the way and see if banking secrecy is sufficiently lifted."



Windows Live just got better. Find out more!

Friday 13 March 2009

Myth of Free Trade and the Secret History of Capitalism

 

AMY GOODMAN: The US government has poured hundreds of billions of dollars into the US economy in the wake of the financial crisis. But what steps are being taken to address the crisis on a global scale? On Sunday, the World Bank warned of the first global recession since World War II, with the world economy set to shrink for the first time since the 1940s. The bank also cautioned that the cost of helping poorer nations in crisis would exceed the current financial resources of multilateral lenders. The economic crisis is projected to push around 46 million people into poverty this year.

 

The financial crisis is forcing some to rethink the neoliberal policies widely blamed for the financial collapse. On Monday, British Prime Minister Gordon Brown called for a new international fund to support poorer countries during the global recession. He also acknowledged richer Western nations have often imposed economic policies on poorer countries that they haven't followed themselves.

 

PRIME MINISTER GORDON BROWN: We will work with the World Bank and our G20 partners to build support for a new fund specifically to help the world's poorest through the downturn. Too often, our responses to past crises have been inadequate or misdirected, promoting economic orthodoxies that we ourselves have not followed and that have condemned the world's poorest to a deepening crisis of poverty.

 

 

 

AMY GOODMAN: Brown says he'll raise the issue of a global fund at the next G20 meeting in July.

 

Well, my first guest has been among the leading economists to criticize the neoliberal policies imposed on poor nations but not followed by the West. Ha-Joon Chang is an economist at the University of Cambridge specializing in developmental economics. In 2005, he was awarded the Leontief Prize for Advancing the Frontiers of Economic Thought. He is author of the books Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical Perspective, and his latest is called Bad Samaritans: The Myth of Free Trade and the Secret History of Capitalism.

 

Welcome to Democracy Now!, as you come from, well, Gordon Brown's country to this one. First, what is your assessment of the situation right now? Warren Buffett has just said that the economy has gone off a cliff.

 

HA-JOON CHANG: Well, I think we are facing the biggest economic crisis since the Great Depression. Now, it probably wouldn't get as bad as the Great Depression, because, unlike in the Great Depression, governments are more willing to intervene with deficit spending and nationalizing financial institutions and giving subsidies to industry and so on, whereas in the 1930s they more kind of adamantly held onto free market doctrines, which they subsequently abandoned, but, I mean, there was a period of time when they just held onto it and lost the opportunity. So I don't think the impact would not be as severe as what it was in the 1930s, but yes, I mean, there's no question that this is as big or possibly even bigger a crisis than what we saw in 1929.

 

AMY GOODMAN: Can you explain what are neoliberal policies? And then you can critique them.

 

HA-JOON CHANG: Yes. Well, basically, the reason why it's called "neoliberal" is that it's a successor to nineteenth century classical liberal doctrine. I mean, "liberal" in American usage usually means kind of the left to the center, but in the European usage, "liberal" means basically belief in the free market and private ownership and basically rule of money.

 

Now, neoliberals have moderated some of the old liberal beliefs. For example, the old liberals actually thought that democracy was bad for capitalism. You know, they thought if you have democracy, poor people vote and create things like income tax, which they have, but, I mean, it actually helped the economy rather than destroyed the economy like the liberals said. So the neoliberals [inaudible] some degree of progressive income tax. The liberals used to be against, for example, having a central bank. The neoliberals actually like the central bank pumping money into the economy when things are going wrong. So it has modified the classical liberal doctrine, but neoliberalism still has, in its core, belief in free market, free trade, deregulated economy and private ownership.

 

AMY GOODMAN: Do you find it funny that you're saying—that Gordon Brown is saying what you have been saying for a while—

 

HA-JOON CHANG: That's right, yeah.

 

AMY GOODMAN: —talking about the hypocrisy of the West? But explain what that is, what the US has done or what the West has done with poorer countries when they're in trouble, and then what we do when we're in trouble.

 

HA-JOON CHANG: That's right, yeah. For example, when the developing countries go into financial crises like the rich countries are experiencing today, they were told by the IMF and the World Bank, and ultimately the rich country governments which control these institutions, that they have to cut spending; ideally, they should run budget surplus. They have to raise interest rate to 30, 50, even 80 percent in some countries. And basically, they have to tighten the belt. Now that the rich countries have the financial crisis, they have cut interest rate to practically zero. You know, I mean, when South Korea had its financial crisis back in 1997, the IMF insisted that the country runs budget surplus equivalent to one percent of GDP. This year in the US alone, budget deficit is estimated to be equivalent to something like 12 percent of GDP.

 

Now, I mean, how do you explain that? I mean, that these policies are not good enough for you? I mean, "We'll use one set of policy, which we think are the good ones, but you have to use something else." You know, the American writer Gore Vidal once upon a time famously said that the American economic system is socialism for the rich and capitalism for the poor, and the international macroeconomic policies have been like that. I mean, it's what I call monetarism for the poor and Keynesianism for the rich. So when the rich countries have a fall in demand, they think nothing of boosting it up by printing money and increasing government spending; the poor countries shouldn't do that.

 

Now, it's not only the macroeconomic policy where this hypocrisy has a role. For example, the rich countries have been telling the developing countries to adopt free trade and told them, "Look, I mean, all countries in history probably, with the possible exception of Japan, have become richer through free trade. So how do you think that you guys can manage it otherwise?" Well, actually, if you look at the British history, American history, you find that today's rich countries used protectionism, center, left and right, when they were developing countries. You know, I mean, for about one century, until the Second World War, the United States was actually the most protectionist country in the world. You know, there's something there when Pat Buchanan said free trade is not free American, because in its 200 years of history, it has practiced free trade only for about fifty years.

 

AMY GOODMAN: We're talking to Ha-Joon Chang, economist at University of Cambridge, just here from London, going back. Bad Samaritans: The Myth of Free Trade and the Secret History of Capitalism is his book. We'll be back with him in a minute.

 

[break]

 

AMY GOODMAN: Our guest is Ha-Joon Chang. He is a world-renowned economist, wrote Bad Samaritans: The Myth of Free Trade and the Secret History of Capitalism. I wanted to ask you about the Obama administration's response to the financial crisis. This is President Obama speaking Friday in Columbus, Ohio.

 

PRESIDENT BARACK OBAMA: Now, there were those—there were those who argued that our recovery plan was unwise and unnecessary. They opposed the very notion that government has a role in ending the cycle of job loss at the heart of this recession. There are those who believe that all we can do is repeat the very same policies that led us here in the first place. But I also know that this country has never responded to a crisis by sitting on the sidelines and hoping for the best.

 

 

 

AMY GOODMAN: President Obama. Your response, Ha-Joon Chang?

 

HA-JOON CHANG: Right. Well, no, I mean, I agree with this sentiment, but the people he put in charge of the economy, like Paul Volcker and Larry Summers, I mean, these are people who actually created this problem. You know, Volcker is, if you like, the godfather of monetarism in this country. And Larry Summers, when he was at the World Bank as the chief economist and then when he was at the Treasury later, I mean, was going around the world preaching to other countries that they have to deregulate their financial market, open up their borders to the American and other rich country financial flows. Now, what they are doing now isn't what they were doing before, but if they have started believing in something else, they should come clean and apologize, don't you think? I mean, because these are the people, with others, who created these problems.

 

AMY GOODMAN: What do you think needs to be done right now?

 

HA-JOON CHANG: Well, I think one important thing that this country needs to do is basically to abandon this obsession with private ownership and go for nationalizing the banks. You know, what the government is proposing now is basically "We'll plug whatever gap that emerges in the banking sector, because if they go down, we go down all together." No, I mean, at one level it's true. But if you want to do that, you have to actually make people answer to these demands. So, now that the taxpayers are paying all this money, why not actually nationalize these banks and make them public servants so that they answer to those who have paid for them?

 

AMY GOODMAN: What do you think of the debate here in the United States, while you're here watching television, the whole controversy over nationalizing the banks?

 

HA-JOON CHANG: Well, I think that this is the legacy of, if you like, neoliberal dominance. I mean, somehow, what you guys call the N-word here is a dirty word. But actually, in the history of capitalism, there are many countries that have run very successful economies on the basis of nationalized banking sector. For example, France until the 1990s, I mean, was basically based on nationalized banking system, and still the government has quite a lot of stake in the banking sector. Singapore, which people believe is some example of free market economy, is actually, in that country, more than 20 percent of national output is produced by nationalized companies.

 

AMY GOODMAN: You're originally from South Korea.

 

HA-JOON CHANG: That's right, yeah.

 

AMY GOODMAN: What about South Korea?

 

HA-JOON CHANG: Well, in South Korea, too, you know, I mean, it didn't use public ownership as much as Singapore or France, but there are very successful companies like POSCO, the steel company, that is now the third largest steel company in the world, was started out as a government-owned enterprise. I think this notion that public enterprises do not work and therefore nationalization will be a disaster, I mean, it's not supported by evidence.

 

AMY GOODMAN: What about nationalization of companies like GM and Chrysler?

 

HA-JOON CHANG: Well, if you—no, I mean, let's play by the capitalist logic. If the taxpayers are paying the money, you have to nationalize them. You know, I mean, the whole problem, people say, is that all these bankers were playing with other people's money. So now, I mean, that they are being paid by the taxpayers, it is only right that the taxpayers control these companies. If they don't want this money and they don't want to be nationalized, they should go bankrupt.

 

AMY GOODMAN: Ha-Joon Chang, I wanted to ask you about Latin America, how leaders there are responding to the economic crisis after decades of following Western demands. Earlier this year, the World Social Forum was held in Brazil. Several Latin American presidents criticized the US for exercising double standards and allowing massive state intervention in financial markets. This is Ecuadorian President Rafael Correa.

 

PRESIDENT RAFAEL CORREA: [translated] The guilty parties in this crisis try to give lessons on morality and good economic handling. The most powerful people on the planet have united to find a therapy for the dying. They're getting together—the central bankers, the representatives of large financial firms, the people primarily responsible for the crisis.

 

 

 

AMY GOODMAN: Ecuadorian President Rafael Correa. He's also a trained economist and was reportedly influenced by your work.

 

HA-JOON CHANG: Yes. I mean, I think he has read my work, and in a number of places, he has quoted me. Yes, but Rafael is only—I mean, the striking examples of a whole group of Latin American leaders which have abandoned neoliberalism and are seeking their own ways. I mean, you know, today, which country in Latin America really listens to the United States? I mean, only Colombia and Chile. And I mean, even Chile now has President Bachelet, who famously joked that the reason why the United States doesn't have a coup d'etat is—unlike Latin America, is that it doesn't have US embassy. And, of course, that led to a diplomatic stir there. But now, even in Paraguay, I mean, the country which was ruled by military dictator General Stroessner for thirty-five years, has this left-wing former bishop as the president. And the whole continent has basically been drifting away from the neoliberal American strategy. And with this crisis, they'll move away even further, unless America changes its approach to the continent.

 

AMY GOODMAN: One of the people you take on big time in your book is Thomas Friedman. Your first chapter, "The Lexus and the Olive Tree Revisited: Myths and Facts About Globalization." We only have a minute to go, but what do you think are the myths that need to be debunked in this country?

 

HA-JOON CHANG: Well, basically, the myth is that America has been founded on the free market; the government has done very little; it has thrived under free trade. But actually, if you look at the history, this is actually the country that has succeeded most with protectionist policies. This is a country which has huge industrial policy, only that it's called research funding in defense industry and research funding in health research. It actually spends, in proportional terms, a lot more money than Japan or European countries in supporting research and development, thereby steering the industries into certain directions. So let's put it this way. I mean, this country has to basically come to terms with what it has done. I mean, it has been haunted by this ideology that, "Oh, we never did anything other than free market and free trade." It's time to give that up.

 

AMY GOODMAN: Do you think that America will continue to be a leader in the world economically, or do you think this is going to fundamentally change its position?

 

HA-JOON CHANG: No, I think in relative terms, it's obviously in decline, but, I mean, it's still, by far, the single richest economy in the world. And, you know, I mean, I give credit where it's due. I mean, it's the only country which became the world hegemony and created room for other countries to rise together. These were the Marshall Plan days, which sadly ended in the '70s, and the US became even more kind of insistent on pushing these wrong policies on the developing countries and some other countries. But, you know, it has a great record, and I think that the country should exploit that history and try to reinvent itself as a new leader in the world.

 

AMY GOODMAN: I want to thank you, Ha-Joon Chang, for being with us. His latest book, Bad Samaritans: The Myth of Free Trade and the Secret History of Capitalism. Safe travels back to Cambridge.

 

HA-JOON CHANG: Thank you.

 

AMY GOODMAN: He's an economist there at the University of Cambridge in Britain.




Windows Live Hotmail just got better. Find out more!

Thursday 12 March 2009

An elite clings on to power

The idea that Pakistan is being 'Talibanised' helps stifle dissent and protect privilege

Markus Daechsel guardian.co.uk, Thursday 12 March 2009

The spectre of "Talibanisation" has taken possession of much recent political commentary on Pakistan. The attacks on the Sri Lankan cricket team in Lahore have become part of the same story as the imposition of "sharia law" in Swat, the bombing of security forces in Peshawar and vigilante action against video shops in Islamabad. This fabric of fear creates the sense of a failing state on the eve of another Islamic revolution and ignores that these are all different kinds of events happening in different places and for different reasons.

Such a narrative is not only an exercise in over-simplification, it is also an important political weapon in the hands of the powerful both inside and outside Pakistan.

The threat of a violent religious takeover hides the highly questionable sources of power on which the current and allegedly secular government of President Asif Ali Zardari depends. The former prime minister, Nawaz Sharif, is not entirely off the mark when he described the prevailing system as an "elected dictatorship" – although it has to be said that his own terms in office had been similarly marred by extrajudicial killings and the willful dismissal of critical bureaucrats. Although Zardari himself has always been trusted somewhat less than his late wife Benazir Bhutto, much of western opinion continues to produce support for his Pakistan People's party at the expense of their (allegedly) more religiously inclined rivals.

William Dalrymple recently claimed in this newspaper that Sindh – Zardari's home province – was a model of peace and tranquility, and that Sufism – the local brand of mystical Islam – should be recommended as an antidote to the Wahhabi extremism of the frontier. What Dalrymple, and others of similar opinion, do not say is that the tranquility in rural Sindh is achieved through the near total power of feudal landowners who pose as secular parliamentarians by day but punish local dissent with greatest brutality at night. The veneration of saints (pirs) that is fundamental to Sufi Islam is an essential component in this network of oppression as most of these saints are closely linked to the landowners by financial and family ties. It was actually the unwillingness of anybody else to represent the grievances of local tenant populations against such landowners in the south of Punjab that gave a first opening to Sunni sectarian groups widely associated with today's "Talibanisation".

Much of what can be described as a "religious turn" in Pakistan today is best explained with reference to increasing social mobility and political mobilisation. The influx of remittances from the Gulf states and elsewhere, a growing urbanisation of the population and the expansion of higher education over the last decades have created both the opportunity and the need for new forms of social identity to millions of Pakistanis. A more visible espousal of Islamic dress, for instance, by first-generation female students or working women represents an attempt to rework old ideas of respectability into more mobile and self-aware forms.

The demand for sharia law similarly acquires a less sinister and reactionary meaning when seen in the local context. Most cases in the official legal system drag on for so long as to financially destroy the economically weaker party regardless of the merit of their claims. The infamous Red Mosque madrassa in Islamabad, which was before its bloody demolition by the Musharraf government in 2007 seen as the very lynchpin of "Talibanisation", did have a large and flourishing section for female students. When interviewed on cable television during the siege, their worried parents turned out to be less religious radical than mainstream conservatives of aspiring working class background. In a country where almost all access to power and economic resources depends on expensive private education, it is unsurprising that they would choose a madrassa as the most affordable option.

The years leading up to the downfall of the Musharraf government saw the emergence of a new and broad coalition of Pakistanis campaigning for freedom of speech, for a more democratic government and for a wider sharing of economic resources. Key to its vibrancy and success was the unfettered journalism of the new private television channels, which has since been curtailed in the name of counterterrorism. This coalition was remarkable because it bypassed much of the old elite and gave little importance to many of the old identity divisions of secular and religious. It started with the organisation of unofficial aid after the devastating earthquake of 2005 and continued in the popular campaign to have the chief justice reinstated; it brought together critical elements in the elite with newly aspiring sections of the population.

The narrative of "Talibanisation" is designed to drive a wedge into this coalition and to persuade the rich and the liberal that their ultimate safety rests with the bastions of old privilege – the military and the feudal elite.

Wednesday 11 March 2009

The New Depression


 

 

By Martin Jacques

10 March, 2009
The New Statesman

 

The financial crisis undermines all the ideological assumptions that have supported political discourse over the past 30 years. Now, with politicians standing 'naked', the crisis could result in profound and diverse changes to our way of structuring the economy, argues Martin Jacques.

 

We are living through a crisis which, from the collapse of Northern Rock and the first intimations of the credit crunch, nobody has been able to understand, let alone grasp its potential ramifications. Each attempt to deal with the crisis has rapidly been consumed by an irresistible and ever-worsening reality. So it was with Northern Rock. So it was with the attempt to recapitalise the banks. And so it will be with the latest gamut of measures. The British government – like every other government – is perpetually on the back foot, constantly running to catch up.

 

There are two reasons. First, the underlying scale of the crisis is so great and so unfamiliar – and, furthermore, often concealed within the balance sheets of the banks and other financial institutions. Second, the crisis has undermined all the ideological assumptions that have underpinned government policy and political discourse over the past 30 years. As a result, the political and business elite are flying blind. This is the mother of all postwar crises, which has barely started and remains out of control. Its end – the timing and the complexion – is unknown.

 

Crises that change the course of history and transform political assumptions are rare events. The last came in the second half of the 1970s, triggered by the Opec oil price spike and a dramatic rise in inflation, which marked the end of the long postwar boom. Its political consequences were far-reaching: the closure of the social democratic era, the rise of neoliberalism, the discrediting of the state, the embrace of the market, the undermining of the public ethos and the espousal of rampant individualism. For the next 30 years, neoliberalism - the belief in the market rather then the state, the individual rather than the social - exercised a hegemonic influence over British politics, with the creation of New Labour signalling an abject surrender to the new orthodoxy.

 

The modalities of this present crisis are entirely different. Extreme as they may have appeared to be at the time, the economic travails of the 1970s were progressive rather than cataclysmic. The old system did not hit the wall, but became increasingly mired and ineffectual. What swept the social democratic era away was not the force de frappe of an irresistible crisis but that it was accompanied by the steady rise of a new ideology and political force in Thatcherism - and Reaganism in the United States - and its victory in the 1979 general election.

 

In contrast, the financial meltdown of 2007-2008 demolished the neoliberal era and its assumptions with a suddenness and irresistibility that was breathtaking. The political class, from New Labour to the Conservatives, is standing naked. They are still clinging to the wreckage of their old ideas while acknowledging in the next breath that these no longer work. The financial crisis is a matter of force majeure; political ideas and discourse change much more slowly, even when it is obvious that the old ways of thinking have become obsolete.

 

Meanwhile, there is no political alternative waiting in the wings, refining its radical ideas in think tanks ready to storm the citadels of power as there was in the 1970s, notwithstanding the fact that think tanks are now far thicker on the ground. Instead, it has been the mainstream which senses that neoliberalism no longer works, fatally undermined by events and, ultimately, the author of its own downfall. This crisis will have the most profound and far-reaching political consequences and will in due course transform the political landscape, but it remains entirely unclear in what ways and when that might be.

 

In all these senses the financial meltdown has far more in common with the Great Depression than the Great Inflation. When the financial crisis consumed Wall Street in 1929 and proceeded to undermine the real economy, engulfing Europe in the process, it was not accompanied by a radical shift towards Keynesianism, but rather a reassertion of sound finance orthodoxy, followed in due course by the adoption of protectionism. The political mainstream as represented by Labour's Ramsay MacDonald and Philip Snowden and the Conservative Stanley Baldwin all sang from the same hymn sheet. Only Keynes and a faction of the Liberal Party enunciated a plausible alternative.

 

Eventually a programme of fiscal deficits and public works was pursued by Franklin D Roosevelt in the United States, but in Britain Keynesianism was not properly embraced until rearmament and the approach of war. Indeed, it was not until 1945 that the combined legacy of war and the Depression belatedly resulted in a fundamental political realignment and the birth of the social democratic era.

 

Since the financial meltdown dramatically intensified in September 2008, Gordon Brown has managed to ride the economic storm rather more successfully than the Conservatives, or, for that matter, than Tony Blair would have done. It is Vincent Cable, the Liberal Democrats' econo­mics spokesman, however, who has indubitably emerged as the political sage, unafraid of confronting neoliberalism's shibboleths, demonstrating a clarity of mind and the political courage to tell things as they are, in a way that has escaped all other prominent politicians.

 

Although Brown was the economic architect of the past decade and was responsible, more than anyone else, for its excesses and was shaping up to be a rather disastrous Prime Minister, he displayed last autumn, at least initially, an agility of mind and nimbleness of foot that defied the expectations of those who believed he was capable of neither. He revelled in the sense of purpose and vision offered by the crisis, seemingly prepared to jettison the thinking that had imbued his previous decade as chancellor.

But Package Part I, widely hailed at the time and imitated elsewhere, proved woefully inadequate, and the financial system remains frozen. Meanwhile the waters are rising up the Good Ship UK, threatening to transform the banking crisis into a fiscal and currency crisis. It seems unlikely that, if that should happen, Brown will survive the next election.

 

Even if it does not happen, Brown faces a serious problem about his own past role, because Britain's crisis has been greatly exacerbated by the soft-touch regulation, easy credit, runaway house inflation and overexpansion of financial services over which he presided and for which he is accountable. So far he has refused to admit or accept responsibility for his actions – he initially had the temerity (or foolhardiness) to argue that the UK was better placed than other countries to deal with the credit crunch, even though it has become abundantly clear since that the very opposite was the case. So while Brown remains in denial, the plausibility of his new turn, and his understanding of what is entailed, must be seriously doubted.

 

Indeed, after its initial boldness, the government now seems trapped by its past actions and its former ways of thinking. Brown's failure to accept the need to nationalise the banks suggests the limits of his new-found political courage, and his inability to embrace the logic and imperatives of the new situation. He is still a prisoner of his old timidity and his conversion to the neoliberal cause.

 

It is his good fortune that the Cameron Conservatives have been hugely wanting in their response to the financial meltdown. Having spent his first years as leader of the opposition seeking to reassure the country of his centrist credentials, David Cameron, at the first whiff of gunfire, has turned on his heels, rejected Keynesianism and, at the very moment when events have shown Thatcherism to be deeply flawed and historically out of time, headed back to the Thatcherite womb of sound finance, arguing that a government must balance its books and that deficit financing, Keynesian-style, is reckless and irresponsible.

 

But all this, it must be said, is the small change of politics. The crisis threatens in time to sweep away the political world as we know it and those who fail to grasp its magnitude and meaning. Far more is at stake than the fortunes of a few leaders, be their name Brown or Cameron. Who knows where things will be this time next month, let alone next year or, indeed, in 2012? The financial meltdown now rapidly plunging the western world into what increasingly looks like a depression is the first great crisis of globalisation. There was plenty of warning. The Asian financial crisis of 1997-98 proved a salutary lesson about the dangers posed by huge capital movements that were subject to precious little regulatory control. Three economies capsized (South Korea, Thailand and Indonesia) and others stood on the brink.

 

There were other earlier warning signs, notably Mexico in 1995, when GDP fell by 9 per cent and industrial production by 15 per cent, following a run on the peso. These crises were blamed on the immaturity and fecklessness of national governments - in the case of east Asia on so-called crony capitalism (which, incidentally, prompts the question of how we should describe Anglo-American capitalism) - which the International Monetary Fund obliged to engage in swingeing cuts in public expenditure as a condition of their bailouts.

 

Yet what if such a crisis were to be no longer confined to the peripheries of global capitalism but instead struck at its heartlands? Now we know the answer. The crisis has enveloped the whole world like an uncontrollable virus, spreading from the US and within a handful of months assuming global proportions, at the same time mutating with frightening speed from a financial crisis into a fully fledged economic crisis. In so doing, it has undermined the foundations on which the present era of globalisation has been built, namely scant regulation, the free movement of capital, a bloated financial sector and immense reward for greed, thereby bringing into question the survival of globalisation as we now know it.

 

Enormous international flows of unregulated capital have capsized the international financial system - with disastrous consequences for the real economy - in a manner akin to the effect of a roll-on, roll-off ferry shipping too much water. We can now see the cost of free-market capitalism and light-touch regulation. Iceland may provide an extreme example of the consequences of the credit crunch but it also illustrates the dangers facing the more vulnerable economies, the UK included, in a deregulated world where the market rules: a small, open economy; a large, internationally exposed banking sector; an independent currency that is not a serious global reserve currency (of which there are only three); and limited fiscal strength.

 

These propositions have constituted the core economic beliefs - from Thatcher and Lawson to Blair and Brown - that have informed policymaking over the past three decades and without which, it was claimed ad nauseam, an economy could not succeed. Heavy-handed regulation and an overbearing state would serve only to frighten off capital and condemn a country to slow growth, stagnation and global marginality. Now we know the fallaciousness of these claims and the consequences of "letting the market decide".

 

Like Iceland, albeit not as extremely, Britain has been living in a fool's paradise.

 

A failure to regulate the banks and other financial institutions in any meaningful fashion allowed bankers to behave in a grossly irresponsible and avaricious fashion; a boom that was made possible only by a government-enabled credit binge in which people borrowed recklessly; a bloated financial sector that grew to represent over 8 per cent of the total economy and which was found to have been built on foundations of sand; an overvalued currency that made manufacturing exports uncompetitive and thereby resulted in an unnecessary and counterproductive contraction in the manufacturing sector which must now be reversed; an absurd belief that boom and bust had been banished for ever, allowing the banks to turn a blind eye to the inflating of various asset bubbles and display a profound ignorance of the history of capitalism; a persistently chronic current account deficit that can no longer be compensated for by inward capital flows; monstrous salaries for those at the top of the financial and corporate tree, which were justified in terms of a trickle-down effect that remained a chimera, and as the reward for risk which was, in fact, a reward for greed and failure; growing inequality, which was justified in the name of a more competitive economy accompanied by declining social mobility in the cause of an open and flexible labour market; and, finally, the mushrooming of what can only be described as systemic corruption on a mega-scale as the state ignored the gargantuan abuses of those who ran the banks and other financial institutions, while regulatory authorities willingly colluded in their excesses.

This is the sad story of the New Labour era.

 

The ultimate cost of this debacle as yet remains unknown. What began as a financial crisis is threatening, as the government seeks to bail out a bankrupt financial sector, to become a currency crisis, with foreign investors concerned about the effects this might have on the value of sterling, and perhaps even worse, ultimately a sovereign debt crisis, with growing doubts about the UK's financial viability.

 

Until there is some end in sight to the financial crisis, and a line can be drawn under the banks' indebtedness, we will not know the answer to these questions. One thing is clear, however: whatever the limitations of the social democratic era, it was never responsible for such an all-enveloping and cataclysmic crisis as the one that the neoliberal era – and the Thatcherites and New Labour – have managed to produce. After all the boasting about the virtues of the Anglo-American model of capitalism, the Grim Reaper has finally spoken: a boom pumped up by credit steroids and a bust that takes us back to the 1930s.

There are two key aspects to this crisis: national and global, with the latter promising to be rather solutions are concerned, we are in uncharted territory, with close to zero interest rates, a Keynesian-style fiscal boost that may prove inadequate to the task and could well fail, a hugely indebted financial sector that threatens to leave us with an enormous future tax burden and a greatly expanded national debt.

 

All of this, furthermore, must be addressed in the context of an open-market regime which is very different from those of previous eras, and which could render Keynesian-style national solutions ineffectual. What would greatly assist any national recovery is a co-ordinated global response to the crisis; in other words, global co-operation at the highest level. This cannot be ruled out, but it would be a brave person that would bet on it. It was exactly the lack of international co-operation that bedevilled recovery in the 1930s and eventually led to the Balkanisation of the world into regional currency and trading blocs.

 

The most important single question in this context is the relationship between the US and China. Will the Obama administration be able to resist the slippery slope of creeping protectionism? Will arguments over the revaluation of the Chinese renminbi be resolved amicably? If the answer is in the negative, then the global outlook will be very bleak indeed and so, also, as a result, will be the prognosis for national recoveries. Indeed, the prospects would look disturbingly like those of the 1930s, with growing international antagonism and friction and a continuingly intractable crisis at a national level, with only the very slowest of recoveries.

Around the world there is growing evidence by the week of a resort to national solutions at the expense of others: measures to subsidise industries that are in severe difficulties; the Buy American clause that was inserted by the House of Representatives into Barack Obama's latest package (though since weakened); the industrial action in Britain against foreign workers; the withdrawal of banks to their national homes; the attack by Timothy Geithner, the US treasury secretary, on China as a currency manipulator. No Rubicon has been crossed but the warning signs are clear. A retreat into protectionism and beggar-thy-neighbour policies will deliver the world into a second Great Depression.

 

So what will be the political effects of the financial meltdown? Some are already evident. Just as the Great Inflation of the 1970s played to the tunes and concerns of the right, with its invocation of the market, the New Depression suggests the opposite, the inherent limitations of the market and the indispensability of the state. Indeed, the speed with which the neoliberal refrains and invocations have unravelled has been breathtaking. The single most discredited aspect of the social democratic legacy was nationalisation, and yet the government, with the most extreme reluctance, has been obliged to nationalise Northern Rock and partially nationalise the Royal Bank of Scotland and the merged Lloyds TSB and HBOS.

 

Who would have ever imagined, at any point during the past 30 years, that no less than the financial commanding heights of neoliberalism would have ended up in the hands of the state, with precious little opposition from anyone except a few disgruntled shareholders? Even now, however, the Labour government, still trapped in the ideological straitjacket of New Labour and displaying extreme timidity in the face of powerful vested interests, which has always been a New Labour characteristic, is running scared of the inevitable logic of the situation, namely that all the high-street banks should be taken into public hands until the mess is sorted out. Anything else leaves the public responsible for all the debts and risks, while the banks continue to be answerable to the very different interests of their shareholders. But such is the fury and depth of the crisis that this scenario is highly likely.

 

The state is experiencing an extraordinary revival. The credit crunch is the most catastrophic example of market failure since 1945. It became almost immediately obvious to wide sections of society that there was only one institution that could potentially sort out the mess: the state. Far from being a rational distributor of resources, the market had proved the opposite. Far from bankers and financial traders embodying the public interest, they have been exposed as irresponsible and dangerous risk-takers whose primary motivation was voracious greed.

 

If trade unionists and the nationalised industries were the demons of the 1970s, bankers and the financial sector have assumed the mantle of public enemy number one in the late Noughties. In fact, the irresponsibility of bankers, and the damage they have inflicted on the economy, hugely exceeds anything that the unions could possibly be held responsible for in an earlier era. Meanwhile, the fallen heroes of the pre-Thatcher era, most notably Keynes, are duly being exhumed, restored to their rightful position, and pored over for their ability to throw light on the present impasse and what might be done; if the recession turns into a depression, Marx will once again become required reading.

 

This political shift is not just a British phenomenon, but a more general western one. The most striking feature of President Obama's inaugural speech was the way in which it embraced and legitimised African Americans for the first time in American history. But it also had another powerful theme, namely its invocation of the public interest and public service. After decades during which American political discourse has been dominated by the language of individualism and the market, it came as a shock to hear a US president articulate a very different kind of philosophy, renouncing private greed in favour of the public good.

 

Obama's election can in part be seen as a response to the failure of the neoliberal era, as well as of Bush's neoconservative agenda; certainly his election represents a remarkable shift to the left in US politics, in contrast not just to Bush, but every recent US president, including Reagan, Bush Sr and Clinton. That Obama is the first African-American president also represents a remarkable redrawing of the political landscape. There is no more powerful - nor difficult - way of redefining society or to embrace a new form of representivity than to include a racial minority that has been excluded.

 

This brings us finally to what might be the longer-term global consequences of the crisis. Again, we are inevitably stumbling around in the dark because so much depends on whether the recession metamorphoses into a fully fledged depression and in what way and shape the world eventually emerges from the debacle. That said, two key points can be made.

 

First, the credit crunch signals the demise of the Anglo-American, neoliberal model of capitalism, which has exercised a hegemonic influence over western capitalism and been the blueprint for globalisation since 1980. Because of its catastrophic failure there seems very little chance of its resurrection. The process of recovery - whenever that might be - will be accompanied by an overriding concern to ensure that the events of 2007-2009 are not repeated in the future, just as happened in the US in the 1930s with the strict regulatory framework that was introduced for the banks after their comprehensive failure in 1929. This will include the search for a new global regulatory framework that controls and constrains international movements of capital, as well as strict controls over the financial sector at a national level. A new set of political priorities - and with it a new political language - will be born.

 

Meanwhile, the influence and prestige that the US, and to a far lesser extent Britain, have enjoyed will vaporise in the same manner as their neoliberal model. Their 30-year project has failed and they will be obliged to pay the price in their reputation and the esteem in which they are held. The countries of the former Soviet Union and the casualties of the Asian financial crisis that were forced to swallow the neoliberal medicine will have good reason to feel aggrieved and resentful. The west has been forthright in accusing the non-western world of corruption. The financial meltdown suggests that the west has been guilty of huge hypocrisy. Systemic corruption has lain at the heart of the western financial system.

 

An entirely disproportionate and extortionate level of bonuses has ensured the enormous enrichment of top executives in the financial sector, all in the name of reward for success, when in fact it was the reward for failure. In addition, we have had the collusion of the credit-ratings agencies; a regulatory system characterised by its failure to act as any kind of constraint; and governments that ensured the continuation of this web of relationships and applauded its achievements.

 

The corruption was on a breathtaking scale as evidenced by the size of the bailouts required to rescue the banks. It will be difficult for western governments to make these kinds of accusations of others in the future. That Obama represents such a voice of hope will help to mitigate the inevitable ill-will towards the US, but this should not be exaggerated amid the euphoria surrounding developments in Washington.

 

The second point is more far-reaching. It is doubtful whether we can still describe ourselves as living in the American era or, indeed, the Age of the West. If not yet quite over, both are certainly drawing to a close, and it seems likely that the effect of the financial meltdown will be to accelerate the rise of China as a global power. The contrast between the situation in China and that in the US could hardly be greater, even though it has been partially obscured by the depressive effect of the western recession on Chinese exports and on China's growth rate.

 

While the US economy is contracting, China's grew at roughly 9 per cent in 2008 and is projected to grow at about 6 per cent in 2009. Its banks, far from bankrupt like their US counterparts, are cash-rich. China enjoys a large current account surplus, the government's finances are in good order and the national debt is small. This is a crisis that emanates from the US and whose impact on China has been essentially indirect, through the contraction of western markets. It is the American model that has failed, not the Chinese.

 

One of the factors that intensified the Great Depression, and indeed was part cause of it, was Britain's growing inability to continue in its role as the world's leading financial power, which culminated in the collapse of the gold standard in 1931. It was not until after the war, however, that the US became sufficiently dominant to replace Britain and act as the mainstay of a new financial system at the heart of which was the dollar.

 

The same kind of problem is evident now: the US is no longer strong enough to act as the world's financial centre, but its obvious successor, namely China, is not yet ready to assume that mantle. This will undoubtedly make the search for a global solution to the present crisis more difficult and more protracted.




Windows Live Hotmail just got better. Find out more!